Case study : Schmeiser case - CiteSeerX

2 downloads 0 Views 136KB Size Report
Centre for Intellectual Property Policy, McGill Faculty of Law, Montreal, ..... jurisdictions, but would also have a chilling effect on the development of new and important ... Association, supported Monsanto in arguing that patents are necessary to ...... New York. TimesNovember 12, 1999, A1. Brown, P., and Vidal, J. (1999), ...
International Consortium on Agricultural Biotechnology Research (ICABR)

8 th ICABR International Conference on

Agricultural Biotechnology: International Trade and Domestic Production

Ravello (Italy), July 8 - 11, 2004

Ag-Biotech in the Courts: Patents, Privileges and Presumptions1 E. Richard Gold, David Castle, L. Martin Cloutier Centre for Intellectual Property Policy, McGill Faculty of Law, Montreal, Quebec, Canada Department of Philosophy, Guelph University, Guelph, Ontario, Canada Department of Management and Technology, University of Quebec at Montreal, Montreal, Quebec, Canada

1

This paper is the product of the work of the Intellectual Property Modeling Group (IPMG) at the Centre for Intellectual Property Policy at McGill University’s Faculty of Law. IPMG members that contributed to the work behind this paper include the authors and the following individuals: Louise Bernier, Ghislaine Cleret de Langavant, Abdallah Daar, Amy Glass and Pamela J. Smith. The authors wish to thank Sven Poysa for his research assistance, Julia Carbone for her editorial assistance, and the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada for financial support.

-2-

ABSTRACT

Through an analysis of a legal dispute between Monsanto and a canola farmer in Canada, this paper identifies some of the assumptions that underlie arguments relating to patents in agbiotech. The authors point out flaws in these assumptions and lay out an alternative framework of analysis that avoids these flaws. This alternative framework provides a transdisciplinary approach to analysing the role of patent systems in encouraging research and innovation, on the development of government policy and on the link between ag-biotech patents and ethical and social concerns.

Keywords : Intellectual property, patents, biotechnology, canola, genetically modified organisms, courts, jurisprudence.

-3Ag-Biotech in the Courts: Patents, Privileges and Presumptions E. Richard Gold Faculty of Law, McGill University

David Castle Department of Philosophy, University of Guelph

L. Martin Cloutier Department of Management and Technology, University of Quebec at Montreal

The application of patent law to agricultural biotechnology has led to dispute and confusion within countries and between countries. Farmers may not be willing to accept, for example, that they cannot save seed from year to year in conformity with traditional practices simply because someone has obtained a patent. Meanwhile, seed developers cite the need for patent protection to compensate them for their investments (Liptak, 2003). At the international level, critics of the patent system accuse it of imposing a western monoculture of knowledge on the developing world (Shiva, 1997). The positions and interests put forward appear to be irreconcilable, leading to deadlock (Gold, 2000a).

In this paper, we explore how the analytical framework we developed elsewhere (Gold et al., 2004) helps us understand and eventually resolve this deadlock. We focus our discussion by analysing an existing legal dispute before the Canadian Courts: Monsanto Canada Inc. v. Schmeiser. This case provides access to the many complex and contradictory forces at play in the patenting and the commercialisation of agricultural biotechnology in Canada and in other countries.

The central feature of this analytical framework is that it is transdisciplinary. It brings together concepts, analytical schemes and tools from several disciplines and thus provides a way to break free of analytical assumptions made within specific disciplines. The framework recognises that like other property rights, patents structure social relationships and

-4transactions and have both anticipated and unanticipated feedback effects. The transdisciplinary approach reveals these effects.

In using or adopting a transdisciplinary approach, one needs to move away from how particular disciplines structure analysis and discussion. That is, rather than examining patents from the point of view, say, of an economist who concentrates on incentives or welfare costs, or as a political scientist examining sources of legitimate and illegitimate power, one must take a broader approach that encompasses the interests of the various parties most affected by the existence (or non-existence) of patent rights. This approach takes interactors as the “lowest common denominator” common to all discipline-based analyses. We therefore structure our analysis and discussion around the three sets of parties: inventors, technology users, and the general public (Waldron, 1993). In the Schmeiser case these are represented, respectively, by industry, farmers (both those who use and those who do not use genetically modified canola), and the courts, public officials and the regulators who work in the public interest.

Following a brief presentation of the facts of the Schmeiser case, we illustrate how the four assumptions that we previously identified played out in the arguments put before the courts by the various parties and participants. We then re-examine the case from a transdisciplinary point of view.

Facts

Monsanto Company is a global provider of agricultural production inputs. The company has operations in “virtually every region of the world,” but it conducts its business activities principally in the United States, Argentina, Brazil, Canada, Australia, France and Japan

-5(Monsanto, 2003a). It is the largest producer of genetically modified seeds (GMOs); almost 90% of the 140 million acres under biotech cultivation worldwide were sowed with the company’s corn and soy seeds (Friends of the Earth, 2003). While the legal dispute technically involves both Monsanto Company and its Canadian subsidiary, Monsanto Canada, we will refer to both as “Monsanto” except where the context requires otherwise.

In 1993, Monsanto Company received a Canadian patent for an invention called GlyphosateResistant plants (Patent ‘830). This patent discloses the invention of a chimeric gene that, when introduced into plant cells, makes the grown plant more resistant to glyphosate, (a broad-spectrum, non-selective herbicide). Both the modified gene that confers the herbicide resistance and cells containing those modified genes are the subject of Monsanto’s patent claims (the Monsanto Claims). As Canada does not provide patent protection over seeds or whole plants, Monsanto received no patent claim explicitly covering entire plants.

Canola tolerant to glyphosate (Roundup Ready canola) first entered the Canadian market in 1996. Since that time, Monsanto has embarked on a program of licensing the right to grow Roundup Ready canola seeds under a Roundup Ready Grower Agreement and a Technology Use Agreement (together, the “TUA”). Under the TUA, the grower may only purchase Roundup Ready canola from an authorized seed agent, agrees to use the seed for only a single planting and to not transfer seed to any third-party or save the seed for replanting. In addition, the TUA obliges the farmer to sell the crop for consumption to a Monsanto-authorized purchaser (Monsanto v. Schmeiser, 2001). Another condition of the TUA requires that farmers use only Monsanto’s Roundup herbicides instead of less expensive generic versions that have become available since the Roundup patent expired in 2000. The TUA also stipulates that Monsanto may inspect the contracting grower’s fields and may take samples to verify compliance. In addition, Monsanto established a ‘1-800’ number to which calls can be made

-6to report the presence of unwanted Roundup Ready seed or to report suspected cases of unauthorized use of the seed.

Percy Schmeiser is a Saskatchewan farmer. According to the court records, he neither purchased Roundup Ready canola seeds nor signed a TUA. However, in 1997 he observed that some of his canola plants were resistant to glyphosate. He then sprayed a limited section of his land (3-4 acres, or about 0.5% of his total canola acreage) to test for herbicide resistance. 60% of the plants survived the spraying, indicating that they were Roundup Ready plants. Nevertheless, as he had done since 1993, Schmeiser harvested the crop from the field, saved some of the seed and planted the saved seed in 1998. Grow-out and “quick” tests revealed that a very high percentage (between 70% and 98%) of the 1998 crop was Roundup tolerant. The resulting crop was included in his canola production that year.

Explanations of the appearance of the Roundup Ready canola on Schmeiser’s land vary. The initial contamination may have been the result of natural biological factors. Monsanto acknowledges that the natural dissemination of pollen and seeds can contribute to the “unintentional mixing” of seed of one plant variety in a different variety (Monsanto, 2003b). At trial, it was shown that a number of local farmers had signed TUAs and were growing Roundup Ready canola on neighboring fields. However, the uncommonly high percentage of Roundup resistant plants suggested, according to Monsanto’s experts, that Schmeiser’s crop was grown from commercial Roundup Ready canola seed and was not the result of seed dissemination or out-crossing. Monsanto first warned Schmeiser against using their seeds without authorization. When Schmeiser refused to stop, Monsanto brought suit for patent infringement.

-7The Federal Court of Canada tried the action. It agreed with Monsanto that Schmeiser had infringed upon their patent. The court held that by having, saving and using Roundup Ready seeds, Schmeiser took the essence of Monsanto’s invention without paying for it, thus infringing Monsanto’s patent. The court effectively interpreted the Monsanto Claims broadly, extending their scope to cover whole plants that contained the patented gene and cells. No argument was presented to the court on this point, all parties seeming to have assumed that the Monsanto Claims covered the entire plants. The court also held that it was not relevant to the patent infringement suit whether Schmeiser actually took advantage of the Roundup resistance of Roundup Ready canola by spraying Roundup. The court held that it was an infringement for Schmeiser to have simply grown the Roundup Ready canola on his land as it was the reproduction of the gene and cells that constituted patent infringement, not using the patented invention in such a way as to extract the value of the invention.

The Federal Court of Appeal upheld the trial decision in favor of Monsanto (Schmeiser v. Monsanto, 2002). The court held that plant material property holders, such as Schmeiser, do not have the right to unauthorized use of patented material. Since Schmeiser used seeds and plants that were subject to Monsanto’s patent rights, Schmeiser infringed the patent. Nevertheless, the court’s reasons did differ slightly from those of the trial court. While agreeing with the latter that Schmeiser’s actual use of the invention, as this was described in the patent application, was not relevant to the question of patent infringement, the court recognized that, in some cases, innocent infringement may not constitute a violation of the patent. The court stated that it might have ruled differently in a case where, unlike the situation in Schmeiser, the farmer would have had no reason to be aware of the presence of the patented gene and had done nothing to cause or promote the propagation of the plant or its progeny.

-8The Supreme Court of Canada, in a 5-4 split, upheld the Federal Court of Appeal decision that Schmeiser had infringed upon Monsanto’s patent but held that Monsanto suffered no damages as Schmeiser had not obtained any value from having used the Roundup Ready seeds (Monsanto v. Schmeiser, 2004). The majority held that Monsanto’s patents in the modified genes and cells were valid. It then turned to the central question that it perceived was at issue: whether Schmeiser used the invention. At this point, the majority significantly changed Canadian patent law by holding that use was dependent on whether the alleged infringer was furthering a “business interest” or “commercial benefit” and not simply on the question of whether the alleged infringer put into practice the particular things described in the patent claim. Presumably, the Court undertook this reworking of what ‘use’ means within patent law to accommodate a potential innocent infringer: a person who not only did not use but had no interest in using the patented invention. On the facts of the case, however, the majority held that as Schmeiser had failed to adequately explain how genetically modified seeds ended up on his land, he had used Monsanto’s invention. However, since he extracted no value from this use – since he had not used Roundup – Monsanto could receive no damages. The dissenting opinion at the Supreme Court took a different view, one arguably more in line with established Canadian patent law. The minority stated that one must interpret patent claims in the context in which they exist. The context in Canadian patent law is that plants are not patentable. Given this, the minority stated, it would not be reasonable to construe a patent over a modified gene or cell as encompassing an entire plant as this would circumvent Canadian law. Thus, while Monsanto had a valid patent, the patent only prevented other seed companies from creating a competing seed. The patent claim did not cover, however, a farmer growing plants containing that seed.

Received Views

-9-

In this part, we examine the views put forward by the various actors in the Schmeiser case and relate them to the four assumptions that we have identified in previous work (Gold et al., 2004). These assumptions underlie much of current academic and applied work relating to biotechnology patents. They structure discourse surrounding patents and the analysis of their positive and negative effects. The assumptions are that 1) patent rights provide necessary incentive to innovate, 2) patents are an optimal policy tool for stimulating research and development, 3) patents create undesirably distributional gradients and 4) patents are ethically neutral.

Our point in relating the four assumptions to the views of the various actors in the Schmeiser case is to highlight how received views coalesce around the assumptions. It is interesting to note that none of the assumptions are seriously contradicted by any of the parties. We leave discussion of the arguments that the parties put forward to later in our analysis.

Assumption I: Patent Rights Provide a Necessary Incentive to Innovate

This assumption holds that patents are necessary to encourage innovation. A company will only invest in developing and commercialising an invention if the company’s returns are larger than its costs. Even if other individuals benefit from the invention, for example, competitors or other companies that use the invention to decrease their costs or increase their revenue, a company will not invest where its own returns are lower than its costs. This is inefficient where the total benefits accruing to the company and other individuals is greater than costs. In such circumstances, society would be better off if the investment had taken place.

- 10 Patents remedy this inefficiency by allowing companies to capture some of the benefit accruing to third parties. Patents provide an inventing company with a right to control access and use of the invention. If third parties wish to extract benefit from the invention, they will need to pay for rights to use the invention. Consequently, the company is able to increase its revenues beyond the benefit it directly receives from its own use of the invention. This gives the company a greater incentive to invest in inventing: an incentive that more nearly matches the entire social benefit from the invention. Viewed in this light, patents are essential to innovation. While this assumption is open to criticism on several important fronts, for now we concentrate on revealing how the players in the Schmeiser case relied upon it in their arguments.

A: Inventors: Monsanto and the ag-biotech industry

The industry’s central message during the court proceedings was the necessity of patent protection for the development of the ag-biotech industry. Patent rights provide companies such as Monsanto with the incentive to conduct research into herbicide resistant plants, to translate that research into a useful product and to disclose information about the modified gene and cells used in that process to the public. The benefits arising from the patent system do not end there. The patent system encourages not only Monsanto’s innovation but other similar innovation that may eventually lower prices, increase consumer welfare and enable access to quality goods.

BIOTECanada, the biotech industry’s national lobby group, argued for the importance of patents to the ag-biotech industry. It went so far as to argue that the Supreme Court of Canada should overrule its earlier holding that animals and plants are not patentable in Canada as this decision put Canada at a competitive disadvantage. BIOTECanada argued that if the Court

- 11 fails to adequately protect biotechnological inventions, “[t]his would have the effect of not only encouraging the flow of investment capital away from Canada to more favourable jurisdictions, but would also have a chilling effect on the development of new and important biotechnological inventions in Canada.”

The Canadian Seed Trade Association, the members of which include seed companies such as Monsanto, argued that intellectual property rights are vital to the Canadian seed industry: “Without appropriate protection mechanisms for seed and plant inventions, Canada may be unable to attract and maintain a thriving agricultural research community.” To deny patent protection, according to the Association, “threatens to place the Canadian seed industry at a competitive disadvantage in relation to Canada’s major trading partners, including the United States, the European Union, Japan, and Australia which allow the patenting of plant genes and cells, and, indeed, of whole plants and seeds…”

Ag-West, an agency established by the Government of Saskatchewan to support the agricultural industry, argued that without patents over ag-biotech “[e]xisting biotech research and commercial entities would be adversely affected in a real and material way. Companies responsible for bringing these useful technologies to the Canadian marketplace would not be likely to continue doing so…”

B: Users: Schmeiser, GM Farmers and Organic Farmers

Schmeiser did not, for his part, challenge the incentive argument. Instead, he concentrated his energies on arguing that, despite the benefits of patents on innovation, social concerns about farming practices and their meaning should override patent rights. He took the position that his freedom to engage in the farming practices of his choice was more important than the

- 12 benefits accruing from genetically modified plants. Schmeiser was supported in his arguments by non-genetically modified canola growers, most notably the organic farming community.

The technology user community was the most heterogeneous of those appearing before the courts. Those who use Roundup Ready seeds, represented by the Canadian Canola Growers Association, supported Monsanto in arguing that patents are necessary to make Canadian farmers more efficient. The Association, representing most of Canada’s canola growers, argued that ag-biotech patents are important to disclose “the science and technology that will encourage additional research and development of further agricultural advances.”

C: The Public: The regulators

None of the agencies that regulate genetically-modified plants made arguments before the courts. However, Agriculture Canada’s literature supports the use of patents and reliance on biotech industry to advance biotechnology research and development in Canada (Agriculture and Agri-Food Canada, 2004) None of the trial or appeal courts examined the reasons why Canada awards patents in the agbiotech area.

Assumption II: Patents are an Optimal Policy Tool for Stimulating Research and Development

A second assumption is that the patent system is the optimal policy tool to foster an innovation economy. Given this, governments, universities and granting agencies should rely heavily on the patent system to produce innovation. The other means of encouraging

- 13 innovation, such as competitive research grants, income tax incentives and the establishment of venture capital funds, are supplementary to the patent system and are not seen as alternatives to it.

Once again, the arguments put forward by the parties illustrate how this assumption is part of the received view.

A: Inventors: Monsanto and the ag-biotech industry

In its arguments, Monsanto as well as the other industry representatives pointed to the clear importance of private sector development, based on a system of strong patent rights, for the development of canola in Canada. Ag-West went so far as to state that “[c]ompanies responsible for bringing these useful technologies to the Canadian marketplace would not be likely to continue doing so if they cannot protect their investment in those technologies, particularly when the world market outside Canada is so huge.”

BIOTECanada, for its part, argued that should Canada fail to recognise patents over plants the “development of new and promising technologies for the benefit not only of Canadians but for all citizens of the world will be inhibited by reducing the level of research and development for biotechnological inventions in Canada.”

Neither the courts nor any of the parties discussed the relationship between publicly financed research and the growth of the canola industry. This omission is striking, as we will discuss later, as canola was developed through public financing without any patent being sought.

B: Users: Schmeiser, GM Farmers and Organic Farmers

- 14 -

In his arguments, Schmeiser suggested that forms of private-sector incentive – such as plant variety protection and trade secrets – make absolute reliance on the patent system unnecessary. Nevertheless, he both accepted the importance of patents and reliance on the private sector to provide society with continued innovation. Schmeiser suggested that Canada could use other means than proprietary rights to encourage innovation. However, he did not challenge the central assumption that it is the private sector armed with proprietary rights that most advances research and development as opposed to the public sector, through its own research and through research grants.

C: The Public: The regulators

Granting agencies have also accepted the assumption that patent rights provide an optimal tool through which to encourage innovation. Increasingly, granting agencies encourage the patenting of funded innovation and tie funding application success to the number of patents that funding applicants hold.

Universities, for their part, place greater emphasis on technology transfer by obtaining and later licensing patent rights over inventions made using their facilities.

Assumption III: Patents Create Undesirable Distributional Gradients

This assumption holds that the patent system is inherently unfair because it sets up distributional inequities by establishing exclusive rights. Patent rights create a disparity of wealth, or aggravate existing disparities, in society by permitting individuals to control access

- 15 to important resources such as biotechnological inventions. This disparity is thought to be particularly unfair given that it relates to our biological heritage.

A: Inventors: Monsanto and the ag-biotech industry

While acknowledging that patent rights place exclusive control over an invention in the hands of the private sector, both Monsanto and the industry interveners argued that this was necessary in order to encourage private industry to develop and commercialise biotechnological inventions that would benefit society. BIOTECanada stated that encouraging innovation through patents in Canada will benefit the “citizens of the world.”

Ag-West strongly argued that the benefits of patents reach far beyond the patent holder. According to its factum, without ag-biotech patents, the “parties or entities harmed will include the biotechnology research and development sector; farmers and their ability to access new technologies and remain competitive in world markets; local, national and international companies; citizens of Canada and elsewhere, who may be denied the products derived from this research; the pharmaceutical sector, into which this technology is expanding; and Canada itself, in that it may not be able to honor contracts with foreign nations to which Canada is a party.”

B: Users: Schmeiser, GM Farmers and Organic Farmers

Schmeiser’s principal argument against Monsanto’s infringement action relied on the inequity of permitting a private actor to exercise control over biological matter. In particular, Schmeiser claimed to be the victim of Monsanto’s economic dominance in the agricultural sector. He stated that patent law was a vehicle through which the powerful could control the

- 16 lives of innocent people, by holding the innocent responsible for what they unknowingly grow on their own land.

Schmeiser argued that the lower court decisions “shift the responsibility for the consequences of ‘gene’ pollution from those who are causing it to those who never sought the modification.” Similarly, a group comprised of various Canadian and international public interest groups including environmental and traditional farmers argued that “[a]n overly broad interpretation of the patent claims may not only interfere with further innovation, a traditional concern of patent law, but also derogate from the existing rights of third parties and adversely effect the environment and biodiversity.” They argued that the Court ought to construe the patent in a manner that takes into account “the serious environmental and biodiversity consequences associated with the use and release of genetically modified and living organisms.” The result of the trial and appeal court decisions was to shift “the burden of contending with the unwanted consequences of the release of this invention into the environment from the patent holder to the public.”

Schmeiser pointed to the fact that he had not even attempted to benefit from the invention since he had not sprayed his crops with Roundup. Thus, he claimed that he did not profit from the advantages of the invention at any point. He stated that it was unfair to award Monsanto compensation for Schmeiser having grown the canola on his land: “By awarding Monsanto Mr. Schmeiser’s entire crop, when its gene added no value, the Federal Court decisions unjustly enrich Monsanto at Mr. Schmeiser’s expense.”

In fact, he stated that he had not altered any of his normal farming practices. As before, he saved seeds, replanted those seeds and sold the resulting crop. Monsanto’s patent infringement suit was an attempt to prevent him from carrying out these ordinary activities by

- 17 making him liable for harvesting crops on his own land. Previously, Schmeiser had developed his own strain of canola and so, he argued, Monsanto’s exercise of its patent rights put an end to this: “The restriction or potential termination of seed saving rights means that individual farmers will not longer be able to develop their own strains.” While he did not specifically argue why it was unjust that Monsanto should have these rights, Schmeiser stated that the patent system unjustly prevents him from carrying on as he had previously.

In contrast, the Canadian Canola Growers Association argued that patents not only benefit the ag-biotech industry, but farmers as well: “Scientific advances are essential for Canadian farmers to maintain and expand their position in the global marketplace. These offer farmers the hope of increased markets and profitability through the development of specialized products.”

C: The Public: The regulators

On one hand, like the biotech industry, government departments in charge of industry and agriculture as well as granting agencies accept that patent rights lead to overall social benefit despite their private nature. Although patent rights may lead to an unequal distributional over inventions, they lead to a broad distribution of benefits.

On the other hand, Ministries of Health are more concerned. The Attorney General for Ontario intervened in the Schmeiser appeal to highlight the effects that patenting biotechnology may have on the health care sector. Specifically, the Attorney General was “concerned that the decision in this case not inadvertently restrict the ability of researchers and health care providers to provide patient care or their ability to develop new tests and treatments for patients.”

- 18 -

For its part, the two lower courts were not oblivious to the concerns of Schmeiser. In fact, the Federal Court of Appeal addressed the possibility of a patent holder pursuing an infringement action against a farmer who did nothing to encourage the growing of a plant subject to patent rights in the following terms:

However, it seems to me arguable that the patented Monsanto gene falls into a novel category. It is a patented invention found within a living plant that may, without human intervention, produce progeny containing the same invention. It is undisputed that a plant containing the Monsanto gene may come fortuitously onto the property of a person who has no reason to be aware of the presence of the characteristic created by the patented gene. It is also reasonable to suppose that the person could become aware that the plant has that characteristic but may tolerate the continued presence of the plant without doing anything to cause or promote the propagation of the plant or its progeny (by saving and planting the seeds, for example). In my view, it is an open question whether Monsanto could, in such circumstances, obtain a remedy for infringement on the basis that the intention of the alleged infringer is irrelevant.

Nevertheless, the Court found that by replanting seeds that he knew to be subject to the patent, Schmeiser was not an innocent infringer.

Similarly, the majority of the Supreme Court of Canada created a small exception for innocent infringement. It did not, however, explain how the exception would actually function and it is unclear from its decision whether the exception would apply to farmers who find out that their fields contain genetically-modified plants.

- 19 Assumption IV: Patents are Ethically Neutral

It is generally assumed that patent systems do not, in themselves, raise any particular ethical issues. While the technology underlying an invention or the terms upon which a particular patent holder licenses use of its technology may have ethical implications – for example, the effects of technology on the environment or the use of license agreement to prevent market entry by would-be competitors – the mere existence of patent rights does not have these implications.

Two elements underlie this assumption. First, patent rights are frequently described as rights to exclude others and not rights to use. Thus, they constitute neither monopoly nor property rights. Given that patent rights neither permit the exploitation of the invention nor are required to exploit an invention, the patent system is disconnected from concerns relating to the use of the technology itself. Second, any ethical concern is more properly dealt with through government regulation of the use of the technology rather than regulation of incentives to innovate.

None of the parties actively engaged in discussion of this assumption.

A: Inventors: Monsanto and the ag-biotech industry

In its factum to the Supreme Court of Canada, BIOTECanada argued that patent rights are not fully constituted property rights by stating “that a patent does not bestow ownership. A patent merely gives the right to the patentee to exclude others.” Presumably, BIOTECanada put forward this point to emphasize that the mere existence of patent rights in living organisms raise no ethical concerns in themselves.

- 20 -

B: Users: Schmeiser, GM Farmers and Organic Farmers

Schmeiser seems also to have accepted that patent rights are not fully constituted property rights in that they only granted the right to exclude others from activity. They do not provide any positive right to use the invention.

The Canadian Canola Growers Association argued that public policy questions had no place in patent disputes: “Parliament has deliberately chosen to keep public policy questions outside the Patent Act.”

C: The Public: The regulators

The courts accepted that Monsanto’s right over Roundup Ready canola was essentially a right to prevent farmers (whether they had or had not agreed to a TUA) from saving, replanting and selling seeds harvested on their property. In particular, both the Supreme Court of Canada and the Federal Court of Appeal made a clear distinction between patent rights and property rights, when discussing conflicts between these rights.

It is not surprising that the courts did not refer to ethical principles in their evaluation of the scope and validity of the Monsanto Claims. The Canadian patent system does not contain an ordre public or morality exclusion. The courts based their decisions on the view that Monsanto’s innovation is crucial for the agricultural biotechnology industry and that this innovation was deserving of strictly enforced patent rights.

Conclusion as to Received Views

- 21 -

As we described in previous work (Gold et al., 2004), the four assumptions described above lead to both incomplete and inaccurate analyses or to both an incomplete and an inaccurate analysis. For example, by narrowing disputed questions to how best hone the incentive provided by patent rights to maximise innovation, these assumptions fail to provide a basis for a contextual analysis. Such an analysis would ask, for example, how the patent system interacts with public funding policies to skew research away from foundational work or how patent law influences intellectual property strategies and commercial relations. As we fully describe these inadequacies elsewhere (Gold et al., 2004), we do not belabour the point.

We suggest that a different, more contextual framework is necessary to overcome the inadequacies of the four assumptions. We propose re-examining the facts and arguments underlying the Schmeiser case using the tools and knowledge outside of the box of any one or two disciplinary silos. By examining these facts and arguments from the perspectives of various disciplines simultaneously, we can better grasp the nature and extent of the issues and better identify how assumptions skew analyses.

Reconceptualisation

In this Part, we re-examine the Schmeiser case using a transdisciplinary approach. We do so by analyzing how patent rights affect those most interested in the inventions: inventors, users and the public. So, instead of focusing attention on maximizing innovation and assuming that this maximization effort benefits society, we examine how patent rights further or harm the interests of the various parties within the contexts in which they operate.

A: Inventors: Monsanto and the ag-biotech industry

- 22 -

Incentive and Access

The primary concern of industry in relation to the patent system is that it provides it with the ability to attract financing to carry on research and, increasingly, development of ag-biotech products and services. Industry perceives patents as one way to ensure an inventor’s ability to recoup its investment in research and development costs and to make a profit.

However, while a single company’s patent rights are believed to be an unmitigated good, patents held by others, particular competitors may interfere with research and development efforts (Phillips and Khachatourians 2001). Patent rights held by third parties represent a cost, both in time and money, to the conduct of research (Heller and Eisenberg, 1998). Should these costs become so significant as to make research and development uninteresting, patent rights would decrease the ability of a company to attract financing.

This double edged-sword – the incentive-access paradigm (Lunney, Jr., 1996) – is well known and analysed. What is less discussed is the absolutist manner in which industry puts forward its patent right claims. This is well illustrated in Schmeiser. As the discussion above indicates, all industry participants took the position that broad patent rights are essential to research and development. None of these parties sought to achieve a balanced set of patent rights that took into account not only the incentive versus access balance, but also the positive and negative consequences of patent rights on technology users or broader social concerns such as the environment. That is, instead of arguing for a patent system with checks and balances, industry argued for the broadest set of rights possible.

- 23 The argument for a broad set of rights is obviously not sustainable. Taking half a pill of acetylsalicylic acid a day may be wise to reduce the risk of a heart attack; but taking a full bottle a day is not healthy. Similarly, patents may be a good thing in some degree, but more and bigger patents are not necessarily best.

One of the central problems that is missed in the assumption that patents are necessary to encourage innovation is that there is a fine line between patent rights acting as incentives to conduct research and pure rent-seeking (Gold, 2000b). At least in the Canadian pharmaceutical context, there is evidence that calls for increased patent rights are undisguised attempts at rent-seeking (Gold, 2001). In the case of Monsanto’s canola, the attribution of rent-seeking is all the more likely when one considers that the value of the innovation can be realized only when bundled with another Monsanto product: Roundup Ready herbicide.

Ethics and Patents

Despite industry arguments that patents have nothing to do with ethics, Monsanto’s own pledge of ethical conduct suggests that industry knows otherwise. In its pledge, Monsanto promises to share its knowledge and technology in order to advance scientific understanding, to improve agriculture and the environment, to improve crops and to help farmers in the developing world. To that end, Monsanto has donated knowledge and technology to assist developing world needs with respect to agriculture. It is particularly interesting that Monsanto acknowledges what it calls the ‘dilemma’ of intellectual property. It describes this as follows:

To balance incentives for innovators and the traditional rights of farmers to save seed from their harvest, a series of plant variety protections and plant patent systems have been adopted in many countries. These systems protect the Inventor’s new product,

- 24 and they provide farmers with more choices than they had before. Farmers still retain the right to replant seeds of varieties in the public domain, just as they always have. Or they can buy protected varieties for a single planting season. Each year they have the choice (Monsanto Company, 2003).

In its pledge, Monsanto acknowledges the importance of choice and of its obligation to provide knowledge and information – including access to patented technology – to developing nations. But both the question of choice and of access to knowledge is mediated through Monsanto’s patent rights. The very fact that Monsanto feels the obligation to make reference to intellectual property in this pledge points to the fact that patents rights have ethical implications.

Needs of the Developing World

Despite the potential of agricultural biotechnology to address the needs of the developed world, current incentive systems seem inadequate to bringing forth that potential for the developing world (FAO 2004). Monsanto’s Roundup Ready canola is, for example, principally a developed world crop as canola is neither a staple nor a commercial crop in most of the developing world (Nuffield Council on Bioethics, 2003). Major companies have had little interest in genetically manipulating and commercialising staple crops of developing countries despite their arguably much larger need in terms of food security and nutritional deficiencies – leaving aside any possible environmental risks (Nuffield Council on Bioethics, 2003; Skerritt, 2000).

It should come as no surprise that the patent system results in large agricultural companies addressing the needs of the developed world over the needs of the developing world. Patents

- 25 are designed to provide a financial return only where there is a market for invention (or the product produced through the invention). Consequently, one cannot reasonably expect the patent system to incite companies to address the needs of poor countries over the needs of developed countries. Given that private industry controls three quarter of the new agricultural biotechnology products (Nuffield Council on Bioethics, 2003) and relies on the patent system to promote innovation, the needs of poor countries will not be addressed.

A distinction needs to be drawn here between low income (countries with an annual per capita income of less than US$765 in 1999 (World Health Organisation, 2001)) and middle-income countries (gross national product per capita equivalent to more than US$756 but less than US$9,265 in 1999 (World Health Organisation, 2001)). The former are unlikely to derive any benefit from the patent system since they simply have insufficient market power to derive any benefit from the patent system’s market-based incentives. However, the later can potentially benefit from the patent system, particularly as they reach the level of technological sophistication to imitate and improve upon agricultural inventions.

We thus need to contextualise the analysis of patents and their effects on the developing world. At one end of the spectrum – the end occupied by low income countries – patents will utterly fail to provide any significant improvement in meeting food needs. This conclusion is not due to any failure of the patent system per se but simply to the fact that the patent system cannot provide incentives where no market exists. Nevertheless, this reality carries moral significance. While it would be wrong to blame the patent system for this, it would be similarly wrong to ignore the patent system’s effect of disproportionately encouraging the expenditure of money on the needs of more affluent countries. Financial resources are limited and asymmetrically distributed. To the extent the patent system encourages its investment in developed world needs, there is less to spend on low income country needs. Thus, while the

- 26 patent system is not morally culpable for failing to address food needs in these countries, the ubiquity of the patent system creates distributional consequences of moral significance.

Middle-income countries present a more complex situation, as seen at the September 2003 Cancun Ministerial Conference. At the Cancun conference, middle-income countries banded together as the G20 Group of countries, presenting a united force that differed in its positions not only from developed countries, but also from that of low-income countries. Middleincome countries have a more ambiguous relationship with agricultural patents. They may benefit from some form of patent rights but would need to explore mechanisms that ensure access to needed technology through compulsory licensing, broad research exemptions, and other measures (Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, 2002).

Whether and to what extent patent rights contribute to innovation depends on the context in which a country’s innovation system operates. While this is most obviously true with respect to developing countries, it is also true of some high-income but middle-sized countries such as Canada

Where Canada Stands

The ag-biotechnology industry is strong in Canada but its major market is the United States (Thomassin and Cloutier, 2001). That is, those investing in research in Canada will reap their returns and profits from product sales to the United States. Since US patent law, and not Canadian law, applies to the US market, returns from Canadian-based research and development depend on US and not Canadian law. On the other hand, researchers in Canada that wish to access patented techniques and materials are governed by Canadian patent law. This gives rise to an interesting dynamic that we now explore.

- 27 -

The traditional incentive-access paradigm is normally thought to apply internally to a country. A country must find a balance between the incentive provided by patent rights and the welfare costs to access created by those rights. In Canada, however, the situation is different. The incentive is established by US patent law; access by Canadian law and so Canada need not do any balancing. Since patents represent a drag on research, Canada is best off reducing the scope of patent rights over ag-biotechnology. This remains true provided that the US cannot reduce patent rights to Canadian researchers. Fortunately for Canada, international trade agreements make it clear that Canada can forego patents over plants and the United States cannot retaliate. Thus, far from undermining Canadian industry incentives to innovate in Canada, the Supreme Court of Canada ruling that plants are not patentable in Canada increases incentives to conduct research in Canada and not the opposite.

B: Users: Schmeiser, GM Farmers and Organic Farmers

Intention and Patent Law

According to the decisions of the trial and appeal court, Monsanto’s patent on the modified gene and cells containing that gene permits it to prevent all others from using, growing or selling Roundup Ready seeds without its authorization. Monsanto only provides this authorization to farmers who agree to be bound by a TUA and to pay a license fee. The problem is that a farmer may infringe upon Monsanto’s patents without knowing that he or she is actually growing Roundup Ready seeds. This could happen, for example, should seeds from a neighbor blow onto the farmer’s land. The existence of Monsanto’s patents thus imposes an economic burden on farmers: the cost of avoiding infringement through the testing of crops and the destroying of contaminated crops. This cost can be very high.

- 28 -

The rule that knowledge is irrelevant to patent infringement may have made sense in the context of 19th inventions contemplated by patent statutes but is problematic in the context of biological inventions. The predecessor to current patent regimes aimed at bringing new manufacturing methods into the legislating jurisdiction, be it 14th century Venice and Florence or 17th century England (Walterscheid, 1994a; Walterscheid, 1994b). The law did not concern itself with invention in the modern sense – e.g. that inventions need to be ‘new’ to the world – but contented itself with encouraging the importation of manufacturing processes to the territory involved so that the skill behind the process could be taught to others.

Pre-modern law therefore provided limited legal monopolies over methods of manufacture. Even current patent laws, enacted in the 19th century, originally focused more on manufacturing than on products themselves. Given this, it is not hard to understand why patent law did not require evidence of intention. A purposeful decision was made to do the acts that constitute infringement regardless of whether the person actually knew that these acts constituted, from a legal point of view, infringement. The same situation is not true of biological materials that can, at least in the appropriate context (e.g., DNA sequences in cells or cells in a living plant), reproduce without human intervention (that is, unintentionally). Since plants have this capacity to reproduce without outside intervention and since a patent granted over the plant (or, as the lower courts ruled, modified genes and cells) also covers all progeny of that plant, infringement – reproducing a particular plant with a particular genetic sequence – can arise without actual knowledge by the farmer. Given the historical reasons for the irrelevance of intention to patent infringement and the nature of biological materials, the fact that intention is irrelevant to infringement in ag-biotech cases raises a distributional question Who ought to bear the burden of lack of knowledge? While it is easy to attribute this burden to those who select the use of an invention, it is far from obvious that this burden

- 29 ought to be imposed on those who do not actively choose to use the invention (Canadian Biotechnology Advisory Committee, 2002).

One way to resolve the problem is to recognize that patent rights are equivalent to property rights and so, like all property holders, Monsanto ought to have both the benefits and obligations relating to the property in question. Therefore, just as someone who negligently uses a baseball bat is liable for injury caused, Monsanto may be liable if it does not take reasonable care in the way it exercises its rights to exclude. For example, it is arguable under current law that Monsanto has not only an ethical, but a legal duty of care to the owners of land neighboring on a farm that has licensed Monsanto’s Roundup Ready canola. Since it is foreseeable that Roundup Ready canola seed can find its way onto that neighboring lands by wind and other means, Monsanto may be liable to those neighboring farmers for any resulting ‘contamination’ (unless Monsanto can has taken appropriate action to prevent this contamination). In order to comply with this obligation, Monsanto may need, for example, to require farmers planting its seeds to obey strict minimum distance requirements between land upon which Roundup Ready canola is planted and neighboring farms. Further, Monsanto may need to enforce this obligation as opposed to merely giving it lip service. It would not be unreasonable to hold Monsanto responsible for the costs of removing unwanted plants since it is in a better position than the neighboring farmer to prevent this loss.

Such an outcome would be particularly welcome by the organic farming community. Because genetically modified canola may so easily contaminate neighboring farms, organic farmers in Saskatchewan can no longer obtain organic certification for many of its products, leading to a claimed loss in the range of $14 million (Organic Consumers Association 2003). The Saskatchewan Organic Directorate has brought suit against both Monsanto and Aventis (another seed company) seeking damages for this loss. If patent holders are held responsible

- 30 for the use of their inventions, then Monsanto and Aventis would internalize the costs of their products on third parties.

Saving Seeds and Ethics

If the Supreme Court of Canada upholds the trial and appeal court decisions in the Schmeiser case, farmers who do not sign a TUA and who do not purchase Roundup Ready canola seed will need to be careful, should they collect previous year’s seed, to ensure that they do not inadvertently include patented Roundup Ready canola seed. This may prove difficult, if not impossible, given the impossibility of testing every seed collected. Nevertheless, failure to ensure complete elimination of such seed in the following year’s crop would constitute patent infringement. The result of this is that farmers, even those who do not buy Roundup Ready canola, may for all practical purposes lose their farmers’ privilege over canola seed given the ease with which there may be intermixing (Canadian Biotechnology Advisory Committee, 2002). Not only does this have distributional consequences – in the form of a loss of rights – but it violates Monsanto’s pledge to offer choice.

It is interesting to note that discussion of the technological solutions to this practical abrogation of farmers’ privilege have existed for some time (Gray and Raybould 1998; Robert and Baumann 1998). One of the technological tools available to Monsanto was a genetic sterilization technique. This so-called (by its critics) Terminator technology would have rendered Monsanto’s genetically modified seed sterile unless a particular chemical was applied to it. In the late 1990s, Monsanto had contemplated, the purchase of Delta & Pine Land, a company that had developed the Terminator technology together with the United States Department of Agriculture. If Monsanto had deployed this technology in its Roundup Ready canola, the canola seed would have only grown once and not been able to reproduce

- 31 naturally thus eliminating the possibility of innocent infringement. This technique would have also permitted farmers to brownbag their seeds – that is, exercise farmers’ privilege – without risk of infringing Monsanto’s patent.

Given this technological fix, one may wonder why Monsanto did not use it. It turns out that Monsanto gave up on the Terminator technology because of fierce opposition to its use by environment groups and those concerned about developing country farmers (Vincent, 1999). The critics of Terminator technology were worried that genetically-modified plants would interbreed with wild varieties, rendering the later sterile. They were also concerned that the technology would absolutely prevent the exercise of farmers’ privilege even in those countries which do not provide patent protection over plants and seeds.

Public opinion in Europe, already turned against genetically-modified plants, turned against the Terminator technology. During a six month period ending on August 24, 1999, Monsanto’s shares lost 11% of their value while Delta & Pine shares fell 18% (Brown and Vidal, 1999). In response, the Deutsche Bank advised investors to dump stocks in companies involved with genetically-modified plants, including stocks in Monsanto. Critics focussed public concern over genetically-modified plants on Monsanto, nicknaming it “Monsatan” and “Mutanto” (Barboza, 1999). The critics used this concern to pressure Monsanto to drop its Terminator technology. In October 1999, Monsanto relented, announcing that it had decided to drop development of the Terminator technology (Feder, 1999).

Given the reason behind the criticism of the Terminator technology – its feared effects on farmers saving seed – it is not without irony that we can conclude today that the decision to withdraw the Terminator technology actually threatens the viability of farmers’ privilege in those countries with patent protection.

- 32 -

Market Power and Patent Rights

Patent rights can act as the springboard for imposing additional contractual obligations on technology users. By requiring growers to sign TUAs rather than simply selling seeds, Monsanto sought to obtain a different economic return than it would normally obtain through its patent rights. It does so in two ways. First, by requiring farmers to agree to the TUA, Monsanto used market power to extend its economic power by requiring farmers to use its Roundup brand of herbicide rather than generic versions of the herbicide. Monsanto was thus able to effectively extend its monopoly powers in the herbicide field even though its patents over Roundup had expired. Second, Monsanto required farmers to refrain from re-using seed and to only sell their plants for consumption to a commercial purchaser authorised by Monsanto. As an aside, these two practices (tied selling and market restriction) could interestingly be analysed in terms of their anti-competitive effects under competition legislation.

C: The Public: The regulators

The history of canola is well documented and is often described as one of the greatest agricultural success stories in Canada. From very uncertain and modest beginnings, canola now provides the greatest annual value of all grain crops in Canada (Industry Canada, 2003). If we actually examine the history of canola, we see that patent rights actually played a very slight role in its development.

Public institutions such as Agriculture Canada and the National Research Council were responsible for the crucial early development of canola (Malla and Gray, 1999). It was not

- 33 until 1990 and the introduction of Plant Breeder’s Rights (PBR) legislation that private research became dominant. By allowing Canadian breeders to apply for intellectual property protection in the canola they developed (although more limited protection than that offered by the patent regime), the legislation stimulated a wave of private investment and a novel award of property rights (Gray, Malla and Ferguson, 2001). While the recent influx of private funding stimulated the emerging biotech industry, most experts agree that canola would not exist as a crop “if it were not for the effort of public breeders.” However true this claim may be, it must be balanced by noting that the success of canola comes at the cost of usurping rapeseed as a viable crop (Kneen 1992).

The recognition of the crucial role of public researchers becomes magnified in light of recent empirical studies. In re-examining the ‘return to research’ for investment in the canola sector (considering, inter alia, the changes to property rights and the introduction of biotechnologies) the authors of the studies focused on the net social benefit from yieldincreasing canola research (Gray, Malla and Phillips, 2002; Malla and Gray, 1999). During the period in question (1960-1997), a large influx of private research investment “induced by property rights and technologies that provided a greater opportunity to capture the benefits from research.” dominated the small public research program. The authors noted that the return on canola research has declined steadily during the period of study. The authors conclude that the combination of property rights (which allow firms to capture the full social benefit of investment) and government subsidies (for private research) lead to over-investment in the industry. Both the history and the empirical studies show that property rights cannot be assumed to provide optimal levels of incentive to stimulate R & D. In fact, the evidence points in the opposite direction: greater private investment triggered by property rights led to inefficient levels of investment.

- 34 Given this history, public agencies – from Departments of Agriculture to granting agencies – ought to be cautious before placing too much emphasis on patents as the method to develop innovation. Curiosity and standing in the research community should not be ignored. Focusing heavily on the patent system as the optimal way to encourage innovation promises, as the canola example illustrates, perhaps unwelcome results.

Conclusion

Although presented to policy-makers as a choice between encouraging the ag-biotechnology industry and protecting the interests of organic and traditional farmers, the Schmeiser case reveals a much more complex reality. Through the transdisciplinary approach that we have undertaken above, we see that industry arguments often lean much more toward rent-seeking for established firms than a true interest in encouraging innovation. Similarly, we see that efforts to prevent certain biotechnologies, such as the Terminator technology, may lead to greater harm.

Our purpose in this analysis was to open discourse surrounding patent rights in agbiotechnology to the reality in which inventions are made and used. While our approach by its nature is more complex than that based on standard assumptions, it leads to significantly more subtle and, ultimately more sound, policy formulation.

- 35 References:

Agriculture

and

Agri-Food

Canada.

(2004)

Federal-Provincial-Territorial

Framework Agreement on Agricultural and Agri-Food Policy for the Twenty-First Century. Ottawa: Government of Canada. http://www.agr.gc.ca/cb/apf/pdf/accord_e.pdf

Barboza, D. (1999), “Biotech Companies Take on Critics of Gene-Altered Food.” New York TimesNovember 12, 1999, A1.

Brown, P., and Vidal, J. (1999), “GM investors told to sell their shares.” The Guardian, August 25, 1999, 1999 WL 23256410.

Canadian Biotechnology Advisory Committee. (2002), Patenting of Higher Life Forms and Related Issues. Ottawa: Government of Canada. http://cbac-cccb.ca/epic/internet/incbaccccb.nsf/vwapj/E980_IC_IntelProp_e.pdf/$FILE/E980_IC_IntelProp_e.pdf

Canadian Biotechnology Advisory Committee. (2001), “Report on President/CEO Briefing to CBAC”,

Gold,

ER,

rapporteur,

http://cbac-cccb.ic.gc.ca/epic/internet/incbac-

cccb.nsf/vwapj/IPPHL_integrated_Pres_Summary_e.pdf/$FILE/IPPHL_integrated_Pres_Sum mary_e.pdf.

Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, (2002). Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and

Development

Policy.

London:

Commission

on

Intellectual

http://www.iprcommission.org/papers/pdfs/final_report/CIPRfullfinal.pdf

Property

Rights.

- 36 Friends of the Earth, (2003). “Trade Business Rules: Who pay the price? How Corporate Influence in the WTO Impacts People and the Environment.” Friends of the Earth International

and

Corporate

Europe

Observatory,

http://www.foei.org/publications/trade/businessrules.pdf , 9

Feder, B. (1999), “Monsanto to Bar a Class of Seeds.” New York Times, October 5, 1999, A1.

Food and Agriculture Organization (2004), The State of Food and Agriculture 2004.

Gold, ER., Adams, WA., Castle, D., Cleret de Langavant, G., Cloutier, LM., Daar, AS., Glass, A., Smith, PJ., Bernier, L (2004) “Shifting Lenses: Biotechnology Innovation and the Patent System.” Public Affairs Quarterly, forthcoming.

Gold, ER. (2000a), “Finding Common Cause in the Patent Debate.” Nature Biotechnology 18, 1217.

Gold, ER. (2000b), “Biomedical Patents and Ethics: A Canadian Solution.” McGill Law Journal 45, 413.

Gray, AJ and Raybould, AF. (1998) Reducing transgene escape routes. Nature 392:653-4.

Gray, R., Malla, S., and Phillips, P. (2002), “Gains to Yield-increasing Research in the Evolving Canadian Canola Research Industry”. In V. Santaniello, R.E. Evenson and D. Zilberman (Eds.), Market Development for Genetically Modified Foods. New York: CABI Publishing. Pp. 113-125.

- 37 Gray, R, Malla, S, and Ferguson, S. (2001), Agricultural research policy for crop improvement in western Canada: Past experiences and future directions. Final report prepared for Saskatchewan Agriculture and Food, http://www.csale.usask.ca/PDFDocuments/agResearchPolicy.pdf.

Heller, M.A. and Eisenberg, R.S. (1998), “Can patents deter innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research.” Science 280, 698.

Hirshhorn, R. and Langford, J. (2001). Intellectual Property Rights in Biotechnology: The Economic Argument. Ottawa: Canadian Biotechnology Advisory Committee, http://cbaccccb.ca/epic/internet/incbaccccb.nsf/vwapj/EcoArgument_Hirshhorn_Langford_e.pdf/$FILE/EcoArgument_Hirshhorn_L angford_e.pdf

Industry Canada (2003), Biotechnology and Consumers: Canola. http://strategis.ic.gc.ca/epic/internet/inbac-bec.nsf/vwGeneratedInterE/h_bk00226e.html

Kneen, B. (1992), Rape of Canola. Toronto: NC Press.

Liptak, A. (2003), “Saving Seeds Subjects Farmers to Suits Over Patents.” New York Times, Sunday, November 2, 2003, I4.

Lunney, Jr., G. (1996), “Reexamining Copyright’s Incentives-Access Paradigm.” Vanderbilt. Law Review 49, 483.

- 38 Malla, S. and Gray, R (1999), The effectiveness of research funding in the Canola industry. A report prepared for Saskatchewan Agricultural Development Fund.

Monsanto Company (2003a). (last accessed October 11, 2003): http://www.pharmaceutical-business-review.com/companyprofile.asp?guid=68BBC79A

Monsanto Company (2003b). http://www.monsanto.com/monsanto/layout/our_pledge/default.asp

Monsanto Canada Inc. v. Schmeiser [2001] FTC 256, para. 96, http://decisions.fctcf.gc.ca/fct/2001/2001fct256.html.

Nuffield Council on Bioethics, (2003). The use of genetically modified crops in developing countries:

a

follow-up

Discussion

Paper.

http://www.nuffieldbioethics.org/filelibrary/pdf/gm_crops_paper_final.pdf.

Organic Consumers Association (2003), Canada: Organic farmers apply for class certification in lawsuit against GMO giants. www.ortganicconsumers.org/organic/011103_0rganic.cfm

Schmeiser

v.

Monsanto

Canada

Inc.

[2002]

FCA

309

http://decisions.fct-

cf.gc.ca/fct/2002/2002fca309.html

Monsanto Canada Inc. v. Schmeiser [2004) SCC 32 http://www.lexum.umontreal.ca/cscscc/en/rec/html/2004scc034.wpd.html

- 39 Phillips, PWB and GG Khachatourians (2001), The Biotechnology Revolution in Global Agriculture: Invention, Innovation and the Investment in the Canola Sector. New York: CABI Publishing.

Robert, S. and U. Baumann (1988), Resistance to the herbicide glyphosate. Nature 396:25-6.

Shiva, V. (1997), Biopiracy: The Plunder of Nature and Knowledge, Boston: South End Press.

Skerritt, JH. (2000), “Genetically modified plants: developing countries and the public acceptance debate.” 2 AgBiotechNet 2, 3. http://binas.unido.org/binas/reviews/Skerritt.pdf

Thomassin, PJ and LM Cloutier (2001), “Informational requirements and the regulatory process of agricultural biotechnology.” Journal of Economic Issues 35, 323-333.

Vincent, C. (1999), “La stérilisation végétale, nouvelle arme biotechnologique” Le Monde, March 12, 1999, 29.

Waldron, J. (1993), “From Authors to Copiers: Individual Rights and Social Values in Intellectual Property.” Chicago-Kent Law Review 68, 841-887.

Walterscheid, EC. (1994a), “The Early Evolution of the US Patent Law: Antecedents (Part I).” JPTOS 76, 697.

Walterscheid, EC. (1994b) "The Early Evolution of the U.S. Patent Law: Antecedents (Part II)." JPTOS 76, 849.

- 40 -

World Health Organisation, (2001). Report on Macroeconomics and Health, Investing in Health for Economic Development. Geneva: WHO. http://www.cid.harvard.edu/cidcmh/CMHReport.pdf