Generalized Delay Differential Equations to

2 downloads 0 Views 1MB Size Report
with constant lags may be preferably solved by using Laplace transforms. Numerous ... where f(t) is assumed to be integrable and of bound- ary variation.
RECENT ADVANCES in APPLIED MATHEMATICS

Generalized Delay Differential Equations to Economic Dynamics and Control ANDRE A. KELLER Universit´e de Lille 1 Sciences et Technologies ´ Centre Lillois d’Etudes et de Recherches Sociologiques et Economiques UMR/CNRS 8019 CLERSECit´e Scientifique 59655 Villeneuve d’Ascq Cedex FRANCE [email protected] Abstract: Dynamic economic models generally consist in difference or differential behavioral equations. Several arguments are in favor of continuous time systems: the multiplicity of decisions overlapping in time, a more adequate formulation of market adjustments and distributed lag processes, the properties of estimators, etc. The type of dynamic equations also refers to historical and practical reasons. In some cases of the economic dynamics, delay differential equations (DDEs) may be more suitable to a wide range of economic models. The dynamics of the Kalecki’s business cycle model is represented by a linear first-order DDE with constant coefficients, in the capital stock. Such a DDE, with constant or flexible lags, also occurs in the continuous time Solow’s vintage capital growth model. This is due to the heterogeneity of goods and assets. In some qualitative study, the time delay is replaced by the Taylor series for a sufficiently small delay and a not too large higher-order derivative. DDEs with constant lags may be preferably solved by using Laplace transforms. Numerous techniques are also proposed for the solution of DDEs, like the inverse scattering method, the Jacobian elliptic function method, numerical techniques, the differential transform method, etc. This study uses a block diagram approach with application to reference economic models, with help of the software MATHEMATICA 6.0. and its specialized packages for signal processing, such as ”Control System Professional”. Key–Words: delay differential equation, method of steps algorithm, differential transform method, Laplace transform solution, Bode diagrams, (x, k)-root plateau.

1

Introduction

form 1 [4] n X m X

The elementary theory of DDEs is introduced by solving and representing simple reference examples. MATHEMATICA plots will show how the parametrized solutions are generated. The technical aspects also concern the differential transform technique, for practical reasons. Two representative applications refer to economics: the earlier Kalecki’s business cycle continuous-time system with a fixed delay [1, 10], and the Solow vintage capital growth control system with a variable delay [3, 5].

i=0 j=0

The subclass of the first-order DDE will then be written a0 y 0 (t) + a1 y 0 (t − ω) + b0 y(t) + b1 y(t − ω) = f (t), where f (t) is assumed to be integrable and of boundary variation.

2.2

2

2.1

Method of Steps Algorithm (MSA)

Let a real-valued DDE with constant delay be  y 0 (t) = f t, y(t), y(t − θ) , t > θ, θ > 0.

Elementary functional differential equation theory

1

The general form is ` F t, y(t), y(t − ω1 ), . . . , y(t − ωm ),

Differential-difference equations

y 0 (t), y 0 (t − ω1 ), . . . , y 0 (t − ωm ), . . . , ´ y (n) (t), y (n) (t − ω1 ), . . . , y (n) (t − ωm ) = 0

The linear form of a DDE of differential order m and difference order n with constant coefficients takes the

ISSN: 1790-2769

aij y (j) (t − ωi ) = f (t).

.

278

ISBN: 978-960-474-150-2

RECENT ADVANCES in APPLIED MATHEMATICS

The method of steps simply consists in extending foreward an initial solution in the direction of incresing t. The equation is solved for each meshpoint {0, θ, 2θ, . . . , kθ, . . . }. Suppose that y 0 t) = y0 (t) is given on [−θ, 0]. The computation process is: At step 1, a solution y(t) = y1 (t) is determined on [0, θ] by solving, analytically or numerically, the resulting ordinary differential equation (ODE)  y 0 (t) = f t, y(t), y0 (t − θ) , y(0) = y0 (θ). Figure 1: Solutions for y’(t)=y(t-1).

At step 2, a solution y(t) = y2 (t) is determined on [θ, 2θ] by solving the resulting ODE  y 0 (t) = f t, y(t), y1 (t − θ) , y(θ) = y1 (θ).

leads to the characteristic equation D(ρ) ≡ ρ + a + be−ρ = 0,

··· At step k, a solution y(t) = yk (t) is determined on [(k − 1)θ, kθ] by solving the resulting ODE   y 0 (t) = f t, y(t), yk−1 (t−θ) , y (k−1)θ = yk−1 (θ). 2.2.1

which possesses many solutions for b 6= 0. We are searching for (a, b)-values for which ρ = jθ, for θ real. Inserting Eq.(2) into Eq.(1), and separating the real and imaginary parts, we obtain a parametric function in θ for a and b, defined by

Dynamics of the Frisch-Holme DDE

Let the Frisch-Holme DDE be [7] 2

a = −θ cot θ, b = θ sec θ.

y 0 (t) = −ay(t) − by(t − θ).

The spectrum of roots of D(ρ) in the complex plane is plotted 3 in the left Fig.2 for (a, b) = (−.5, 1). The figure to the right shows the stability regions in the (a,b)-plane. The solutions are either monotonic or oscillatory. The extension to a linear (linearized) system

With the parameter values a = 0, b = −1, θ = 1, the DDE is now y 0 (t) = y(t − 1). Let the initial function be simply set to y0 (t) = 1, at period 0. The ODE to solve at next period will be y 0 (t) = y0 (t − 1), y(1) = y0 (1), at period 1, and that of the next period will be y 0 (t) = y1 (t − 1), y(2) = y1 (2), a.s.o. The solutions are represented in Fig.1. The solutions are given by y(t) =

n X (t − k)k k=0

2.2.2

k!

(2)

, t ∈ [n, n + 1], n ∈ N0 .

Stability of the Frisch-Holme DDE

The stability of all solutions is acheved asymptotically, provided that all the characteristic roots lie in the negative complex half-space [4, 8, 11]. Searching for solutions of the form √ y(t) = ceρt , ρ = α + jβ, j = −1 (1)

Figure 2: Stability domain for y 0 (t) + ay(t) + by(t − θ) = 0

2 Kalecki (1935)[10] early retained a similar DDE for the macroeconomic system 3 √ The characteristic equation D(ρ) = 0 with ρ = α + βj, j = −1 is numerically solved for (a, b) = (−.5, 1). The set of equations to be solved is {a + α + be−α cos β = 0, β − be−α sin β = 0}. The roots can be computed by using a NewtonRaphson method, with adequate starting values.

m m + nθ y (t) = y(t) − y(t − θ), θ θ 0

for which a main cyclical solution is obtained for the parameter values: m = .95, n = .121 and θ = .6 (7 months). ISSN: 1790-2769

279

ISBN: 978-960-474-150-2

RECENT ADVANCES in APPLIED MATHEMATICS

of DDEs introduces the matrix equation [6]

2.3.2

Application to the Kalecki’s system

m X y0 (t) = A0 y(t)+ Ai y(t−θi ), Ai ∈ Rn×m , i ∈ Nm ,

The continuous-time Kalecki’s business cycle system (1935)[10] is

i=1

Y (t) = C(t) + I(t), C(t) = cY (t), c ∈ (0, 1), Z 1 t I(t) = B(τ )dτ, θ t−θ  B(t) = λ vY (t) − K(t) , λ ∈ (0, 1),

whose characteristic equation reads m X  det D(ρ) = ρI − A0 − Ai e−ρθi = 0. i=1

2.3

Differential Transform Method (DTM)

K 0 (t) = aK(t) − bK(t − θ), K(0) = 1, (10)   λv v where a = θ(1−c) and b = λ 1 + θ(1−c) . Using the

F (k)(t − t0 )k .

k=0

The transformation of usual functions is presented in Appendix B. Let a DDE take the general form   f g (n1 ) (t+θ1 ), g (n2 ) (t+θ2 ), . . . , g (np ) (t+θp ) = 0,

Table B.1, we obtain the transformation of Eq.(10) ¯ + 1) − aK(k) ¯ (k + 1)K(k  T  X h1 ¯ 1 ) = 0. +b (−1)h1 −k − K(h k

(3) with the boundary conditions (BCs)

h1 =k

g (ai ) (t)|t=bi = ci , i ∈ Nm .

¯ The unique BC is also transformed to K(0) = 1. Taking for numerical values λ = 2/5, θ = 1, c = 3/4, v = 1/2, the coefficients are a = .8 and b = 1.2. Choosing T = 4, with the BC and k = 0, 1, 2, 3 and taking for numerical values , a linear system in the ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯ variables K(1), K(2), K(3), K(4) is solved. We have the system

The differential transformation D[.] of the BCs is given by T X k=0

(9)

The aggregate demand in Eq.(5) of consumption C and investment outlays I equals the total revenue Y . In Eq.(6), consumption is proportional to the total revenue. In Eq.(7), the investment orders depend on the past investment decisions B with a fixed delay of θ. The determination of the investment decisions, in Eq.(8), is proportional to the gap between the desired level of equipment vY (t) and the existing capital stock K. According to Eq.(9), a fixed delay separates the deliveries of capital goods from the orders. After some algebraic manipulations 4 , the system may be reduced to a linear first-order DDE with constant coefficients, in the variable K(t)

The transformation of the kth derivative of a function f (t) is 1 F (k) = f (k) (t)|t=t0 , k! and the inverse transformation is defined by ∞ X

(8)

K (t) = B(t − θ).

Introduction to the method

f (t) =

(7)

0

The approximate solution of DDE by using the Zhou’s differential transform method was extended by Arikoglu and Ozkol (2006)[2]. The method is used to solve linear and nonlinear DDE with variabke coefficients. 2.3.1

(5) (6)

k−ai k! G(k) bi − t0 = ci , i ∈ Nm . (k − ai )!

Theorem 1 [2] Let G(k) = D[g(t)], the solution of Eq.(3) depends on the solution of the unknown coefficients G(0), G(1), . . . , G(T ). We have   Fk G(0), G(1), . . . , G(T ) = 0, k ∈ N0,T −m .

¯ ¯ ¯ ¯ .2K(1) − 1.2K(2) + 1.2K(3) − 1.2K(4) ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯ .4K(1) − .4K(2) + 3.6K(3) − 4.8K(4) ¯ ¯ ¯ .4K(2) − .6K(3) + 7.2K(4) ¯ ¯ .4K(2) − .8K(4)

(4) Eq.(4) consists in m equations, the remaining T −m+ 1 standing from the transformation of Eq.(3).

= = = =

.4, 0, 0, 0.

4

The integral Eq.(7) is also written as Z t+θ ` ´ I(t) = θ−1 K 0 (x)dx = θ−1 K(t + θ) − K(t) ,

Proof. See Arikoglu and Ozkhol (2006)[2]. 

t

where x = τ + θ. ISSN: 1790-2769

280

ISBN: 978-960-474-150-2

RECENT ADVANCES in APPLIED MATHEMATICS

We obtain the solution ¯ ¯ ¯ K(1) = −.56, K(2) = −.4, K(3) = .0533, ¯ K(4) = .0266. Using the inverse transformations from Table B.1, the series solution for the problem is divergent with K(t) = 1 − 1.56t − .4t2 + .0533t3 + .0266t4 + O(t5 ).

3 3.1

Generalized DDE for economic systems Kalecki’s business cycle model with discrete delay

The Laplace transform of the system Eq.(5-9) is 1 1 ¯ I(s) − u ¯(s), Y¯ (s) = (1 − c) (1 − c) 1 θs ¯ ¯ I(s) = (e − 1)K(s), θ ¯ = λv Y¯ (s) − λK(s), ¯ B ¯ ¯ sK(s) = e−θs B(s), where the initial conditions are zero and where u(t) denotes the input of the system. The Laplace trans¯ formed variables X(t) are written L[X(t)] = X(s). ¯ Solving the system w.r.t. K(s), the transfer function is ¯ K(s) φ(s, θ)λv ,  = u ¯(s) (1−φ(s,θ))λv (1 − c) s + φ(s, θ)λ − θ(1−c)

Figure 3: Bode diagrams for different delays

where φ(s, θ) = e−θs is approximated by the Taylor’s 2 2 series 1 − θs + θ 2s + O(s3 ). Taking the parameter values λ = 2/5, θ = 1, c = 3/4, v = 1/2 and a unit delay θ = 1, the transfer function is s2

2 3s22 2

−s+1 −

s 2

+1

.

The constant is 2 (about 6 dB), the zeros are the√complex conjugates 1 ± j, so as the poles 16 (1 ± j 23). The Bode diagrams in Fig.3 of the transfer function show the response of the system to a sine signal. The impact of a shorter/longer time delay is illustrated in Fig.4.

3.2

Solow vintage capital growth model with variable delay

Figure 4: Impact of time delay on simulation results

The purpose of a growth model with heterogeneous productive capital, is to determine the optimal age structure of machines by taking adequate investment decisions. ISSN: 1790-2769

281

ISBN: 978-960-474-150-2

RECENT ADVANCES in APPLIED MATHEMATICS

3.2.1

The function Ψ(t) is a ratio between the labor requirement of the new machines at t to the replaced ones at t − T (t) [5].

Equations of the system

The Solow vintage capital growth system consists of four equations. The first two equations describe the vintage technology 5 and the market good equilibrium.The next two equation concern the labor market (labor demand and equilibium). We have 6 Z

3.2.3

The MSA cannot be extended directly to the timevarying state-dependent DDE    0 y (t) = f t, y(t), t t − θ(t, y(t) ,

t

y(t) = t−T (t) Z t

l(t) =

i(τ )dτ,

(11)

i(τ )e−a(τ )τ dτ,

(12)

 where θ t, y(t) is the lag function of time t and state variable y(t). In fact, the successive meshpoints {0, σ1 , σ2 , . . . , σk , . . .} will differ from each other and are unknown. At each step k, the meshpoint σk+1 must be determined given the computed solution y(t) = yi+1 (t) on [σi , σi+1 ] for i = 0, . . . , k. The equation

t−T (t)

i(t) = (1 − c)y(t), l(t) = 1.

(13) (14)

Eq.(11) represents an AK technology (A = 1) in the vintage productive capital, where all existing machines are supposed to be in use. The variables are defined by: production y, investment i, age T of the oldest machine, and τ a generation of machines. Eq.(12) is the labor demand l(t). Each machine at t requires e−a(t)t workers, and new machines are more 0 productive, since the elemrnt a(t)t with a(t)t > 0 denotes the technological progress. According to the equilibrium condition Eq.(13) of the good market, a fixed proportion 1 − c of income is saved and totally invested. Since the labor supply is assumed to be constant over time, the equilibrium condition on the labor market is defined by Eq.(14). 3.2.2

σk+1 − θ(σk+1 , y(σk+1 )) = σi is solved for the meshpoint σi corresponding to the smallest σk+1 > σk . One illustration of the process is given by Boucekkine et al. [5]. Suppose that the generalized DDE is given by  y 0 (t) = y t − θ(t) , where the lag function is defined by θ(t) = t + sin t and the initial function y0 (t) = 1. At the step 1, for i = 0, i ∈ {0, 1} we have to solve y 0 (t) = y0 (t) = 1 on [0, σ1 ]. We find the solution y(t) = y1 (t) = 1 + t. At this step, for i = 1, we have to solve y 0 (t) = y1 (− sin t), which give condradictory results on [0, 2π]. Indeed, the solution of y 0 (t) = − sin t + 1, y(0) = 1 is t + cos t on [0, 2π], whereas the solution of y 0 (t) = − sin t + 1, y(π) = 1 + π is 2 + t + cos t on [π, 2π]. Since, the smallest value may be chosen in practice, we retain σ1 = π. The modified algorithm then introduces two substeps for each step of the MSA [5]: (i) Replacing the solution yi (t) on [σi−1 , σi ] for i = 0, . . . , k in the DDE, the resulting ODE is solved and gives yk+1 (t). (ii) The largest meshpoint value σk+1 is such that 0 yk+1 (t) is consistent with the DDE over [σk , σk+1 ]. The solution is y(t) = yk+1 (t) on [σk , σk+1 . The numerical code used by Boucekkine et al. [5] is based on the 5th-order Runge-Kutta method.

System of DDEs with flexible delays

The differentiation of the system Eqs.(11 − 14) leads to a system of two DDEs in y 0 (t) and T 0 (t) with flexible delays 7 . We have  y 0 (t) = (1 − c)y(t) 1 − Ψ(t) , y(t)  Ψ(t), T 0 (t) = 1 − y t − T (t) where Ψ(t) = e−a(t)t /e−a



t−T (t) × t−T (t)



.

5 The productive capital stock is made up of different homogeneous vintages [1]. Each vintage consists of a comparable set of machines, in use at t but installed at t − T . 6 This presentation is inspired from Boucekkine et al.[5]. 7 Differentiating Eq.(11), we obtain « „ ` ´ ` ´ 0 0 y (t) = (1 − c) y(t) − y t − T (t) × 1 − T (t) .

A

Laplace transform solution of equation y 0 (t) = −by(t − 1)

The Laplace transform (denoted by L[.]) method is used to solve a first-order linear DDE:

The differentiation of Eq.(12) leads clearly to l0 (t) = 0, which is solved w.r.t. T 0 (t). ISSN: 1790-2769

Modified Method of Steps Algorithm

y 0 (t) + by(t − 1) = 0, t > 0, 282

(A.1)

ISBN: 978-960-474-150-2

RECENT ADVANCES in APPLIED MATHEMATICS

which boundary conditions are y(t) = 0, t ∈ [−1, 0], where b is a constant. We know that8 L[y(t)] = Rand ∞ y(t1 )e−st1 dt1 = Y (s), s ∈ C, and L[y 0 (t)] = 0 sY (s) − y0 . Multiplying Eq.(A.1) by e−st , and integrating from 1 to infinity, we have also Z ∞ Z ∞ 0 −st y (t)e dt + b y(t − 1)e−st dt = 0. (A.2) 1

From Eq.(A.6), Y (s) may also be expressed as Y (s) =

p=0

1

Applying the theorem 2, we have

Let us examine the two integrals of Eq.(A.2). Integrating by parts the first integral and assuming y(t)e−st → 0 as t → ∞, we obtain Z ∞ Z ∞ 0 −st −s y (t)e dt = −y(1)e + s y(t)e−st dt. 1

 ∞ est X p p+1 s(t−p) p+2 y(t) = y0 ds, − (−1) b e /e s (c) p=0 I  I ∞ X est s(t−p) p+2 p p+1 = y0 ds− (−1) b e /s ds . (c) s (c)

1

p=0

Giving that (see [12], p.8) ( n I h ehk n! , = n+1 0, (c) k

−1

1

= by0 e−s

Z

0

e−st dt + be−s

Z



y(t1 )e−st1 dt1 ,

−1

−1

 y(t) = y0 1 −

by0 (1 − e−s ) = + be−s Y (s). (A.4) s Placing Eqs.(A.3) and (A.4) into Eq.(A.2) yields

B

(−1) b

DTM Performances)

Let a nonlinear DDE with backward-foreward delays, and variable coefficients 10 y 00 (t) − e−t y 0 (t − 1)y(t + 1) = 0,

(A.6)

(B.1)

where the BCs are: y(0) = y 0 (0) = 1, t ∈ [0, 1]. The exact solution is clearly et . Using the table B.1 11 , knowing that D[e−x ] = (−1)k /k!, we obtain the transformation of Eq.(B.1)

Theorem 2 [12]. Let f (t) be integrable over every R∞ finite interval such that (i) 0 f (t)e−st converges absolutely on the real line Re s = c and that (ii) f (t) is of bounded variation in the neighborhood of t, then   I 1 st f (t + 0) − f (t − 0) , F (s)e ds = 2 (c)

(k + 1)(k + 2)Y (k + 2) −

where the LHS is a contour integral taken along the line from c − jT to c + jT in the complex plane9 .

k2 k X X

T X

T X

 (k1 + 1)

k2 =0 k1 =0 h1 =k1 +1 h2 =k2 −k1

 ×

The inverse Laplace transform is given for a suitable c by Z c+j∞ L−1 [Y (s)] = (2πj)−1 Y (s)est ds = y(t).

h2 k2 − k1



The contour integral is represented by I Z c+jT 1 F (s)est ds. F (s)est ds ≡ lim T →∞ 2πj c−jT (c)

h1 k1 + 1



(−1)h1 −k1 −1 Y (h1 )Y (h2 ) ×

c−j∞

ISSN: 1790-2769

 − p)p+1 , (p + 1)!

p p+1 (t

where [t] denotes the largest integer less or equal to t.

by0 (1 − e−s ) + be−s Y (s) = 0. (A.5) s Solving Eq.(A.5) for Y (s) and assuming that s − e−s 6= 0, we get

9

[t] X p=0

sY (s) − y0 +

by0 y0 − . s s(s + be−s )

Re h > 0, Re h < 0,

we obtain the solution

 st 0 e −s = by0 e − + be−s Y (s), s −1

Y (s) =



I

(A.3) Using a change of variable for the second integral yields Z ∞ Z ∞ −st y(t1 )e−s(t1 +1) dt1 , y(t − 1)e dt = b b

8

y0 by0 − −s , s s2 (1 + b e s )   ∞ 1 X p p+1 −ps −p−2 − . = y0 (−1) b e s s

(−1)k−k2 = 0. (k − k2 )!

10

This example is drawn from [2] with adapted notations, and using the package MATHEMATICA. 11 The Table B.1 of usual differential transforms is issued from the theorems by Arikoglu (2006) [2]. 283

ISBN: 978-960-474-150-2

RECENT ADVANCES in APPLIED MATHEMATICS

The BCs are also transformed to Y (0) = Y (1) = 1. Choosing T = 8, with the BCs and k = 0, 1, 2, a nonlinear system in Y (1), Y (2), . . . , Y (8 is solved 12 . Using the inverse transformations from Table B.1, the series solution for the problem is obtained y(t) = 1 + t + .499973t2 + .166615t3 + .041599t4 +.008289t5 +.001373t6 +.000187t7 +.000016t8 +O(t9 ).

f(t)

F(k)

g(t) ± h(t)

G(k) ± H(k)

c g(t)

c G(k1 )

tn

( 1, δ(k − n) = 0,

k=n k 6= n

g(t) h(t)

Pk

− k1 )

g (n) (t)

(k+n)! k! G(k

p(t) g (n) (t)

Pk

The errors increase significantly with time in Fig.B.1.

Figure B.1: DTM performances

C

Tinbergen’s shipbuilding cycle

g(t + a)

limT →∞

PT

h1 =k

×ah1 −k G(h

Characteristic equation

Let the form of the unknown function be y(t) = eρt , the characteristic equation from Eq.(C.1) is D(ρ) ≡ ρ + be−ρθ = 0, ρ ∈ C,

(k−k1 +n)! h1 =0 P (k1 ) (k−k1 )!

(C.1)

It is also assumed that y(t) = h(t), t ∈ [0, θ), where h(t) is some given function. In this application to the shipbuilding industry, y denotes the deviation of the tonnage from a mean value and θ a given constant construction time. In this equation, Tinbergen assumes the rate of new shipbuilding to be proportional to a delayed tonnage deviation, with a one to two years delay θ and a ranged intensity reaction b ∈ [ 12 , 1]. An endogenous cycle is found for the shipbuilding industry, with a period of 7 years 6 months for θ = 1 and 8 years 9 months for θ = 2.

C.1

+ n)

×G(k − k1 + n)

The Tinbergen’s equation [13] is of the form 13 y 0 (t) = −by(t − 1), b > 0, t > θ.

k1 =0 G(k1 )H(k

(C.2)



h1 k



1)

g (n) (t + a)

(k+n)! PT lim T →∞ h1 =k+n   k! h1 h −k−n a 1 G(h1 ) k+n

p(t) g (n) (t + a)

P P limT →∞  kk1 =0 Th1 =k−k 1 +n h1 (k−k1 +n)! (k−k1 )! k − k1 + n ×ah1 −k+k1 −n P (k1 )G(h1 )

Table B.1: Differential transforms F (k) = D[f (t)]

12

Solving the nonlinear system by using the primitives of MATHEMATICA, 128 solutions are obtained. The 20 real solutions are shown in Fig.B.1 to the left. 13 A nonlinear DDE version is given by [12] y 0 (t) = −by(t − 1) − εy 3 (t − 1), ε, b > 0.

ISSN: 1790-2769

284

ISBN: 978-960-474-150-2

RECENT ADVANCES in APPLIED MATHEMATICS

√ where ρ = β + αj, j = −1. Inserting Eq.(C.2) into Eq.(C.1) and separating the real and imaginary parts, we get the system cos u = sin u u

=

we get C = 1. The solution of the DDE Eq.(C.1) is a pure exponential 16 of the type y(t) = (C1 + C2 t)eρt .

−v v e , θb 1 v e , θb

For C > 1, the solutions are composed of two expo-

where u ≡ αθ and v ≡ βθ. Eliminating v, we obtain an even function f (u) in which the structural coefficients θ, b are not explicit. We have f (u) =

u sin u + ln = C, tan u u

(C.3)

where C ≡ − ln(θb). A further analysis of the characteristic equation is given by Pinney [12] by means of the (x,k)-root plateau in the parameter space14 . The properties of the characteristic equation are summarized in Fig.C.1(see also [9])

Figure C.2: Exponential behavior nentials in the period ranges   θ θ T ∈ , , k ∈ N. k k − 12

Figure C.1: Characteristic equation properties

C.3 C.2

A cycle corresponds to each real solution of Eq.(C.4) when C < 1. The two sides of this equation are represented in Fig.C.3. Real branches of f (u) decrease monotically in all the intervals [k2π, (2k + 1)π], k ∈ N0 . According to u = αθ and α = 2π T , the corresponding period ranges are   θ θ , , k ∈ N0 . T ∈ k k − 12

Existence of exponential components

Let z ≡ ρθ, Eq.(C.2) may be expressed as −

z = e−z . θb

(C.4)

The two parts of Eq.(C.2) are plotted 15 in Fig.C.2. The condition for tangency of the two curves 1/(θb) = e−z is z = ln(θb). Inserting in Eq.(C.3),

The sine curves may be damped or undamped. A dictinction is made between the major cycle of the first period and the minor cycles The corresponding patterns of components are shown in Fig. C.4.

14

According to this concept, the parameters may be chosen in order to achieve some desired properties for the system. Let the complex number be ρ = x + jy, the (x,k)-root plateau represents the sets of parameter values for which the caracteristic equation has k pseudo roots greater than x. The equations of the (x, k)-root plateau on the b-line are Re D(ρ)

=

x + be−x cos y,

Im D(ρ)

=

y − be−x sin y.

References: [1] R.G.D. Allen. Macro-Economic Theory: a Mathematical Treatment. MacMillan, London– Melbourne–Toronto, 1967.

15

Fig. C.2 shows a state of a dynamic interactive MATHEMATICA plotting, with automatic sliders and controls. ISSN: 1790-2769

Existence of cyclical components

16

285

A degenerate cycle with infinite period. ISBN: 978-960-474-150-2

RECENT ADVANCES in APPLIED MATHEMATICS

[2] A. Arikoglu and I. Ozhol. Solution of differential-difference equations by using differential transform method. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 181:1155–1175, 1999. [3] M. Bambi. Endogenous growth and time-tobuild: the ak case. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 32:1015–1040, 2008. [4] R.E. Bellman and K.L. Cooke. Differentialdifference equations. Technical Report R-374PR, The RAND Corporation, Santa Monica, Cal., 1963. [5] R. Boucekkine, O. Licandro, and C. Paul. Differential-difference equations in economics: on the numerical solution of vintage capital growth models. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21:347–362, 1997. [6] K. Engelborghs and D. Roose. On stability of lms methods and characteristic roots of delay differential equations. SIAM Journal of Numerical Analysis, 40(2):629–650, 2002. [7] R. Frisch and H. Holme. The characteristic solutions of mixed difference and differential equations occuring in economic dynamics. Econometrica, 3(2):225–239, 1935.

Figure C.3: Cyclical pattern

[8] E. Hairer, S.P. Nørsett, and G. Wanner. Solving Ordinary Differential Equations I: Nonstiff Problems, Second Revised Edition. Springer Series in Computational Mathematics. SpringerVerlag, Berlin–Heidelberg–New York, 1993. [9] N.D. Hayes. Roots of the transcendental equation associated with a certain differencedifferential equation. Journal of the London Mathematical Society, 25:226–232, 1950. [10] M. Kalecki. A macroeconomic theory of business cycle. Econometrica, 3(3):327–344, 1935. [11] V. Kolmanovskii and A. Myshkis. Introduction to the Theory and Applications of Functional Differential Equations, volume 463 of Mathematics and Its Applications. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht–Boston–London, 1999. [12] E. Pinney. Ordinary Difference-Differential Equations. University of California Press, Berkeley–Los Angeles, 1959.

Figure C.4: Pattern of the components

[13] J. Tinbergen. Ein Schiffbauzyklus ? Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 34(2):152–164, 1931.

ISSN: 1790-2769

286

ISBN: 978-960-474-150-2

Suggest Documents