Impact of Control Type on Firm Growth in Taiwan

9 downloads 377 Views 101KB Size Report
Abstract In this research we work with cross-sectional data for 300 Taiwanese corporations to find possible impact of control type on firm growth. We model firm ...
Chen, Kiani, and Madjd-Sadjadi, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 76-84

76

Impact of Control Type on Firm Growth in Taiwan Ellen Hui-Ru Chen*, Khurshid M. Kiani**, and Zagros Madjd-Sadjadi*** Southern California Edison*, University of the West Indies – Mona**, and Winston-Salem State University***

Abstract In this research we work with cross-sectional data for 300 Taiwanese corporations to find possible impact of control type on firm growth. We model firm growth for these corporations with and without growth constraint that is incorporated in our models using discriminant analysis dividing corporation data into two groups S and W. Our results from the models that do not incorporate growth constraints show that the variable Profits/Sales is statistically significant and is positively related to the firm growth. The results do not change much for class S when we analyze data for the two classes, i.e. S and W separately using the models that encompass growth constraints. However, for class W, Debt/Equity is the only statistically significant variable which is positively related to the firm growth in Taiwan. Keywords: discriminant analysis; owner-controlled firms; management-controlled firms; control type; firm growth JEL Classifications: C31, C40, D92

1. Introduction Researchers since Berle and Means (1932) have considered the problem of separation of ownership and control. It is because managers tend to obviate profit maximization of the corporation which is against the wishes of the owners (Lee 1990). Contrary to that, Claessens, and Djankov (1999) show a positive link between highly concentrated firm ownership to a high level of firm profitability supporting the notion of owner controlled rather than manager controlled firms. On the other hand behavioral and managerial theorists developed alternative conception of the firm based on managerial interests. These ideas reveal that managers might deviate from traditional profit-maximization and set other goals, such as lifetime income (Monsen and Downs 1965), sales volume (Baumol 1959), growth rate (Marris 1964), or staff expenditure (Williamson 1964). However, Cowling (2004) contradicts Marris’ finding on existence of a trade-off between growth and profit. Profit-satisfying, rather than profit-maximizing, behavior may be the norm (Colli 2003) for some owners, the notion of owners as being solely interested in profits, especially in the context of family-run and closely-held firms, is questionable as they might have additional goals that are separate and distinct from pure profit-maximization. Penrose (1995) characterizes owners as being of one of two categories. These are the product-minded entrepreneurs who care about their

Chen, Kiani, and Madjd-Sadjadi, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 76-84

77

products and empire builders who are concerned to capture a large market segment of the industry. Complexity of corporate relationships leads to asymmetric information which makes it difficult for dispersed stockholders to monitor manager’s performance when control is separated from the ownership (Jensen and Meckling 1976). This issue can be solved tying managerial compensation to performance (Leibenstein 1966). However, when corporations display significant degrees of market power (Williamson 1964), if capital markets have imperfections (Smiley 1976), or when managers receive incomplete contracts concerning incentives (Williamson 1985), or when it is difficult to replace managers due to low mobility (Fama 1980), managerial performance and owner expectations are more likely to differ. In this paper, we investigate whether control type has any impact on firm growth. To attain this objective, we explicitly incorporate a growth constraint in our models through discriminant analysis to anticipate possible impact of control type on firm growth (if any). The remaining paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we present an overview of corporate governance in Taiwan. Section 3 presents data and econometric analysis, and section 4 shows empirical results. Finally, section 5 incorporates conclusions that can be drawn from the paper.

2. Corporate Governance in Taiwan Lang, Claessens and Djankov (1999) pointed out that out of the nine Asian countries they studied many small and old firms are owner-controlled and even over half of the 2980 corporations they studied were controlled by a single shareholder. Additionally they pointed out that many small and older firms were owner controlled. Likewise, Taiwan has a higher degree of family-owned or controlled large corporate enterprises. Claessens, Djankov, and Lang (2002) noted that there tends to be a large degree of separation of management from control within family firms in the Asian region, especially in Taiwan. Although separation of management from control is evident within the larger firms in Taiwan, this separation is often illusionary because managers may be picked more on the basis of loyalty to the family than due to managerial competence. In addition, corporate governance structures in Asia are not very well organized and there is a great risk of minority shareholder rights expropriation (Claessens and Fan 2002; Johnson et al 2000). This can lead to greater profitability in some respects but it reduces accountability, which has been noted as one factor causing the East Asian economic crisis of the late 1990s (Iu and Batten 2001).

3. The Econometric Model Based on the literature review and structure of corporate governance in Taiwan, we separate Taiwanese firms in two broad groups and generate a growth constraint using discriminant analysis. The growth constraint obtained from the discriminant analysis is subsequently used in time series model for possible existence of the impact of control type (if any) on firm growth in

Chen, Kiani, and Madjd-Sadjadi, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 76-84

78

Taiwan. Discriminant analysis and time series models are elaborated in the following subsections. 3.1 Discriminant Analysis A safety constraint disciplines managers by threatening them to end their tenure. It is because when control is separated from ownership, managers might be more interested in corporate growth than its profitability. Likewise, lack of managerial resources and the possibility of corporate takeovers or shareholder auditing of managerial performance can also be used as safety constraint (Penrose 1995). Therefore, we employ discriminant analysis on the variables corporation assets, profits, and share holding of the managers in Taiwanese corporations to classify them into strong binding growth (S) and weak binding growth (W) groups based on a grouping variable that initially characterizes the firms based on whether 20 percent or more of the shares were held by the largest shareholder. Results from discriminant analysis that are presented in Table 2 show that out of a total of 154 closely-held firms, only 145 are identified as class S firms where the remaining 9 are identified as class W firms. Likewise, 139 out of 146 widely-held firms are segregated as class S whereas the remaining 7 firms are segregated in class W firms. These results reveal that most Taiwanese firms fit into class S wherein managers are bounded by growth constraints that do not allow them to act against the owner’s wishes. 3.2 Time Series Model The growth constraint generated from the discriminant analysis is incorporated into our time series model. In this model, the dependent variable is the average growth rate for fixed assets in the year 2000. The most general time series model employed in this paper is shown in the following Equation: G = α + β1* Percent + β2 * TYPE + β3 * Strong + β4 * AGE + β5 * Assets + β6 * Profits / Sales + β7 * Debt / Equity + β8 * Liquidity + ε

(1)

where, growth of corporation (G) is the dependent variable, Percent, TYPE, Strong, AGE, Assets, Profits/Sales, Debt/Equity, and Liquidity are independent variables, and ε is an error term. TYPE is a dummy variable that takes on zero for closely-held firms and one for widely-held firms, and variable AGE measures the age of firms. The inclusions of variables employed in our models are due to a number of studies including Mueller (1972), Evans (1987), Oliveria & Fortunato (2004) and Lee (2004). Table 1 provides a description of all the variables employed in our models. However, we dropped the variable TYPE from our final model because it had negligible impact on the predictability of the endogenous variable in the model.

Chen, Kiani, and Madjd-Sadjadi, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 76-84

79

4. Data Sources and Empirical Results 4.1 Data Sources We work with cross-sectional data on 300 Taiwanese corporations to investigate possible impact of control type on firm growth in Taiwan. We obtained data for these firms for the year 2000 from the publications of the Taiwanese Management Securities Commission (http://www.SFC.gov.tw, Vol. 20, No. 1, 2002) and the Review of the Investment Information (http://www.smartnet.com.tw, No. 12, 2002). 4.2 Empirical Results Regression results without discriminant analysis are presented in Table 3. These results reveal that Assets, Profits/Sales, the intercept terms, and percent are statistically significant, whereas the remaining variables are insignificant at all levels. Likewise, results from the model that encompass managerial growth constraint are shown in Table 4. This Table presents regression results for class S and class W firms, including the p-values for the parameter estimates. Most firms in our sample are in class S; therefore class W firms can be thought of management controlled firms because of the weakly binding growth constraint. The results for strongly binding growth constraint firms (class S) show that the variable Profits/Sales is positively related to the growth of the firm and is the only statistically significant variable. The variable AGE, though not statistically significant, is negatively related to firm growth, showing that well established firms grow slower than newer firms. Results for weakly binding growth constraint firms (class W) show that Assets and the Debt/Equity ratio are positively related to firm growth. This implies that manager-controlled firms grow by leveraging the assets of the firms whereas the owner-controlled firms fund their growth from their profits. Gedajlovic and Shapiro (2002) argue that Taiwanese firms are controlled more by family relationships than would be obvious by merely looking at the extent of holdings by these individuals. This control is maintained through cultural norms and the placement in management of members of the family. 4.3 Hypothesis of Interest The chief hypothesis of interest of this paper is whether the owner-imposed growth constraint has an impact (if any) on the growth of the firms. We explicitly included a growth constraint in our models through discriminant analysis to see if control type due to Berle and Means (1932) has any significant effect on the growth of the firm. Our results do not show statistically significant evidence of control type on firm growth in Taiwan. However, we found statistically significant evidence that weakly binding growth constraint firms tend to finance their growth through leverage. Contrary to this, the strongly binding growth constraint firms finance their growth from earned profits. Firms in Taiwan mostly consist of class S firms which avoided usage of borrowed funds for firm growth. This is

Chen, Kiani, and Madjd-Sadjadi, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 76-84

80

crucial in understanding why Taiwan did not suffer much when compared to the other economies in the region in 1997 Asian Financial crises.

5. Summary and Conclusions In this paper we investigate the empirical validity of the growth hypothesis due to Berle and Means (1932). Our results are fully parametric and we explicitly incorporate a growth constraint in our time series models using discriminant analysis to investigate the impact of control type on firm growth. Our study results reveal that the growth constraints are strongly binding which segregates most of the Taiwanese firms into class S. These results also show that most firms in Taiwan are segregated into class S and did not finance their growth from external borrowings compared to class W firms that grew through external finance. Moreover, class S firms also exhibited much lower profit rates, lending some credence to the idea that such firms willingly obviate opportunities for risky short term profits in exchange for steady long term sustainability.

Chen, Kiani, and Madjd-Sadjadi, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 76-84

81

Endnotes * Financial Analyst, Southern California Edison, 2244 Walnut Grove Ave., Rosemead, California 91770. Tel: (626) 302-1118. Email: [email protected]. **Corresponding Author: Department of Economics, The University of the West Indies, Mona, Kingston 7, Jamaica, W.I. Tel: (876) 512-3015. Fax: (876) 977-1483. Email:[email protected], or [email protected]. ***Department of Economics, Winston-Salem State University, Winston-Salem, North Carolina,

27110. Tel: (336) 750-2398. Fax: (336) 750-2335. Email: [email protected].

References Berle, A. and G. Means. 2003. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: McGraw-Hill. Baumol, W. J. 1959. Business Behavior, Value and Growth. New York: Macmillan. Claessens, S. and S. Djankov. 1999. “Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performance in the Czech Republic: C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers,” CEPR Discussion Papers: 2145. Claessens, S., S. Djankov, and L. Lang. 2000. “The Separation of Ownership and Control in East Asian Corporations,” Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2), 81-112. Claessens, S. and J. P. H. Fan. 2002. “Corporate Governance in Asia: A Survey,” International Review of Finance, 3(2), 71-103. Colli, A. 2003. The History of Family Business, 1850-2000. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press. Cowling, M. 2004. “The Growth-Profit Nexus,” Small Business Economics, 22(1), 1-9. Evans, D. S. 1987. “Tests of Alternative Theories of Firm Growth,” Journal of Political Economy, 95(4), 657-674. Fama, E. 1980. “Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm,” Journal of Political Economy, 88(2), 288-307. Gedajlovic, E. and D. M. Shapiro. 2002. “Ownership Structure and Firm Profitability in Japan,” Academy of Management Journal, 45(3), 565-575. Iu, J. and J. Batten. 2001. “The Implementation of OECD Corporate Governance Principles in Post-Crisis Asia,” Journal of Corporate Citizenship, 4, 47-62.

Chen, Kiani, and Madjd-Sadjadi, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 76-84

82

Jensen, M. C. and W. H. Meckling. 1976. “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305-360. Lee, F. S. 1990. “The Modern Corporation and Gardiner Means's Critique of Neoclassical Economics,” Journal of Economic Issues, 24(3), 673-693. Lee, W. 2004. “Financial Structure, Corporate Finance and Growth of Taiwanese Manufacturing Firms,” Working Paper, National Taiwan University, Taiwan. Leibenstein, H. 1966. “Allocative Efficiency vs. X-efficiency,” American Economic Review, 56(3), 392-415. Lang, L. H., P. Claessens, and S. Djankov. 1999. “Who Controls East Asian Corporations?” The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series: 2054. Monsen, R. J., Jr. and A. Downs. 1965. “A Theory of Large Managerial Firms,” Journal of Political Economy, 73(3), 221-236. Morris, R. 1964. The Economic Theory of Managerial Capitalism. London: Macmillan. Mueller, D. C. 1972. “A life Cycle Theory of the Firm,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 20(3), 99-219. Oliveria, B. and A. Fortunato. 2004. “The Dynamics of the Growth of Firm: Evidence from the Service Sector,” Working Paper, Superior School of Technology and Management, Polytechnic Institute of Leiria, LEIRIA, PORTUGAL. Penrose, E. 1995. The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. New York: Oxford University Press. Smiley, R. H. 1976. “Tender Offers, Transaction Costs and the Theory of the Firm,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 58(1), 22-32. Williamson, O. E. 1964. The Economics of Discretionary Behavior: Managerial Objectives in a Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Williamson, O. E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.

Chen, Kiani, and Madjd-Sadjadi, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 76-84

83

Table 1. Description of Variables Included in Our Models Percent Strong AGE Assets Profits/Sales Debt/Equity Liquidity

This variables denotes the percentage of shareholders by the largest shareholder. Strong is a dummy variable that takes on a value of 1 for strong binding firms and 0 otherwise. AGE is the number of years elapsed since the inception of the firm. Assets denotes the value of the firms assets in millions of New Taiwan dollars. Profits to sales ratio. Debt to equity ratio that determines the long-term financial stability of a firm. Liquidity ratio that determines the short-term financial stability of a firm.

Notes: In this Table, column 1 shows the names of the variables and column 2 gives the description of these variables.

Table 2. Results of Discriminant Analysis Description Closely-held firms Widely-held firms Average profit rate (%) Value of the Average Executive Share (New Taiwanese dollars) Average Size (in millions of New Taiwanese dollars)

Class W 9 7 4.38

Class S 145 139 0.16

9,613,613

1,282,260

193,710

11,700

Notes: In this Table, column 1 shows the description of the variables used in our analysis. Columns 2 and 3 show discriminant analysis results which segregate owner-controlled and manager-controlled firms in classes W and S respectively, based on year 2000 data on Taiwanese corporations. This Table shows three variables (average profit rates, average shares of executives and average size of corporations) employed to discriminate Taiwanese corporations data into two categories with probabilities proportional to group size.

Chen, Kiani, and Madjd-Sadjadi, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 76-84

84

Table 3. Regression Results without Discriminant Analysis Variables Intercept Percent Strong AGE Assets Profits/Sales Debt/Equity Liquidity Sample Size Adjusted R-Square D.W.

Parameter Estimates -31.5064 0.2169 13.898 -0.0883 0.0002 0.5429 0.1185 -0.0035 300 0.1753 1.9298

P-values (0.0108) (0.0777) 0.1133 (0.5422) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.1534) (0.7726)

Notes: In this Table, column 1 shows the description of the variables used in our analysis. Column 2 illustrates parameter estimates for all the variables included in the model, and p-values for each parameter estimate are juxtaposed in parentheses column 3.

Table 4. Regression Results with Discriminant Analysis Variables Intercept Percent AGE Assets Profits/Sales Debt/Equity Liquidity

Sample Size Adjusted R-Square D.W.

Class S -13.7012 (0.1115) 0.1903 (0.1327) -0.0979 (0.5182) 0.0011 (0.5419) 0.5121 (0.0000) 0.1379 (0.2918) -0.0040 (0.7411)

Class W -113.211 (0.0843) 0.2960 (0.6398) -1.1900 (0.1569) 0.000 (0.0762) 0.4660 (0.3703) 2.8060 (0.0208) 0.07200 (0.5908)

284 0.1146 1.8681

16 0.6422 2.1960

Notes: In this Table column 1 shows the description of the variables used in our analysis. Column 2 exhibits parameter estimates for class S and column 3 for class W firms. P-values for each are shown beneath each parameter estimate in parentheses.