Leo Stanley

10 downloads 0 Views 662KB Size Report
4.1 A hard learning process: Lesson 1 – Argentina . ... predominant neoliberal vision perceived increased financial activity as beneficial ..... macroeconomic crisis, making clear the incapability of the model to increase .... following the crisis34.
Capital  inflows,  bank  deregulation  and   financial  institutions:  from  repression  to  crash?   Argentina  and  South  Korea  compared.       Leonardo  E.  Stanley,  CEDES   ∗

                                                          CENIT-­‐GDAE-­‐RIS   “Towards   Inclusive   and   Development-­‐Friendly   Global   Economic   Governance:  Evolving  a  Southern  Consensus”.  A  Ford  Foundation  funding  Project.                                                                                                                     ∗

 Associate  Researcher  at  CEDES,  e-­‐mail:  [email protected]    

Index   1.  Introduction  .........................................................................................................................................  2   2.  A  Micro  –  Macro  approach.  ............................................................................................................  6   2.1  Macro:  The  case  for  capital  controls  ..................................................................................  6   2.2  IMF  lesson  1:  Argentina  ...........................................................................................................  9   2.3  IMF  lesson  2:  South  Korea  ....................................................................................................  15   2.4  Micro:  Beyond  Basle  regulation  .........................................................................................  20   3.  An  Institutional  perspective  ........................................................................................................  28   3.1  Liberalization  at  both  multilateral  and  bilateral  ........................................................  28   3.2  Argentina  institutional  path  towards  globalization  ..................................................  33   3.3  The  KORUS  FTA  and  South  Korea  rupture  with  the  past  .......................................  38   4.  Conclusions  ........................................................................................................................................  44   4.1  A  hard  learning  process:  Lesson  1  –  Argentina  ...........................................................  44   A  hard  learning  process:  Lesson  2  –  South  Korea  .............................................................  47   A  hard  learning  process:  Lesson  3  –  Crisis,  what  crisis?  ................................................  48   6.  References  ...........................................................................................................................................  51   7.  Annex:  Tables  and  Graphs  ...........................................................................................................  58  

 

1  

“Unrestrained  convertibility  in  the  capital  account  is  in  fact  a  luxury,   desirable  in  itself,  enjoyed  by  a  handful  of  countries  which  have  either  a   very  developed  or  a  very  underdeveloped  domestic  financial  system”.   Carlos  Diaz  –  Alejandro,  1984      

1.  Introduction   In   the   past,   foreign   shocks   spread   to   national   economies   mainly   through   trade   channels,   and   transmission   of   such   shocks   took   time.   After   globalization   and   increasing   capital   account   liberalization,   shocks   arrive   at   domestic   financial   markets   almost   immediately.   When   coupled   with   financial   deregulation,   freeing   completely  the  capital  flows  might  certainly  increase  the  probability  of  a  crisis.  In   this   sense,   countries   with   larger,   better-­‐developed,   and   more   open   financial   systems  did  worst  in  the  last  crisis.  As  a  result  many  countries  are  taking  a  more   nuanced   view   regarding   the   role   of   short-­‐term   foreign   capital,   after   recognizing   that  such  inflows  may  give  rise  to  asset  bubbles  and  macro  instability.       To  same  extent,  the  actual  situation  began  its  trend  after  the  collapse  of  the  Bretton   Woods   system   in   the   earliest   1970s,   implying   the   irruption   of   a   new   flexible   exchange  rate  system  and  the  dismantling  of  former  controls  on  capital  flows.  The   shift   towards   free   markets   becomes   accelerated   with   the   coming   to   power   of   Margaret   Thatcher   and   Ronald   Reagan   in   1979   and   1980   respectively.   The   predominant   neoliberal   vision   perceived   increased   financial   activity   as   beneficial   for   development   and,   Keynesian-­‐Myskian   caveats   were   set   aside.   By   the   same   token,   the   efficient   market   hypothesis   substituted   Keynes´   beauty   contest   parabola   of  how  financial  market  actually  behaves1.  That  was  the  central  message  arriving   from   the   developed   world,   and   being   vociferated   by   the   International   Financial   Institutions   (IFIs),   throughout   a   collective   of   instructions   enclosed   under   the   Washington  Consensus.  Henceforth,  rescue  package  originated  at  the  International                                                                                                                  

1  Financial  market  deepening  via  capital  account  liberalization,  henceforth,  could  spread  the  benefits  

on  a  worldwide  basis.  Barry  Eichengreen  (1999)  summarized  the  idea  “There  are  clear  benefits  from   being   able   to   borrow   internationally.   Capital   mobility   creates   valuable   opportunity   for   portfolio   diversification,   risk   sharing,   and   intertemporal   trade.   By   holding   claims   on   foreign   countries,   households   and   firms   can   protect   themselves   against   the   effects   of   disturbances   that   impinge   on   the   home   country   alone.   Entrepreneurs   can   pursue   high-­‐return   domestic   investment   projects   even   when   domestic   finance   is   lacking.   Capital   mobility   can   therefore   enable   investors   achieve   higher   rates   of   return.  And,  higher  rates  of  return  can  encourage  saving  and  investment,  ultimately  supporting  faster   rates  of  growth”.  

 

2  

Monetary  Fund  (IMF)  or  World  Bank  (WB)  lending  practices,  both  introduced  new   clauses  of  financial  deregulation  and  capital  account  fully  convertibility.  Under  this   new   framework,   developing   countries   were   urged   to   liberalize   their   capital   account   and   deregulate   their   financial   sector.   In   other   words,   a   micro-­‐macro   initiative   was   under   operation.   Sooner   than   later   Wall   Street   began   to   move   forwards   the   institutionalization   of   this   scenario,   both   at   the   bilateral   and   multilateral  foray.     International  investment  agreement  (IIAs)2  would  swiftly  become  at  the  centre  of   a  new  legal  framework  supporting  the  liberalization  task3.  Financial  liberalization   was   also   integrated   at   the   Uruguay   round,   and   numerous   new   instruments   were   soon   launched   at   the   newly   created   WTO,   including   those   introduced   by   the   General  Agreement  on  Trade  in  Services  (GATS)4.  Henceforth,  either  on  a  bilateral   or  multilateral  basis,  developing  and  emerging  economies  passed  through  a  [legal   or   institutional]   process   of   financial   deregulation   and   capital   account   liberalization.   Certainly,   since   the   early   1970s   financial   flows   become   to   increase   at   amazingly   rates,   benefiting   to   emerging   and   developing   countries.   Capital   inflows   were   certainly   not   aside   from   cyclical   downturns   and   sudden   stops.   A   group   of   Latin   American   countries   experimenting   with   financial   liberalization   abruptly   become   aware   of   this   sort   of   problems.   Policies   were   mainly   oriented   towards   ease   the   domestic   market   up   from   government   intervention.   Advances   at   the   institutional   front   were   not   severe,   however.   From   a   micro   perspective,   the   banking   industry   remained  weakly  supervised.  At  the  institutional  front,  developing  countries  policy   space  remained  uncontested,  as  legal  constraints  were  absent  at  the  international   level.   Twenty   years   later   most   countries   in   the   region   embarked   on   a   neoliberal   path,   including   new   and   deepest   financial   liberalization   measures.   Financial                                                                                                                   2  

Among   others,   IIAs   include   the   following:   Bilateral   Investment   Treaties   (BITs),   Free   Trade   Agreements   (FTAs),   Regional   Trade   Agreements   (RTAs),   and   Economic   Partnership   Agreements   (EPAs).     3   Initially   built-­‐in   a   bilateral   format,   investment   liberalization   will   spread   later   under   a   free   trade  

scheme.  Particularly,  following  the  signal  of  the  North  American  Free  Trade  Agreement  (NAFTA).   4  It  might  be  also  consider  the  Agreement  on  Trade-­‐Related  Aspects  of  Intellectual  Property  Rights   (TRIPs),  and  the  Trade-­‐Related  Investment  Measures  Agreements  (TRIMs)    

 

3  

deregulation   included   now   a   more   pressing   stance   on   banking   surveillance   and   accountability.  In  the  movement  towards  financial  liberalization  and  deregulation   a   group   of   developing   countries   and   emerging   economies   accepted   to   reduce   capital  regulations,  including  the  reduction  (or  elimination)  of  controls  on  capital   inflows.  A  group  among  them  went  further  accepting  to  institutionalize  this  stance,   either  by  accepting  more  liberalizing  commitments  at  the  WTO  sphere  or  by  virtue   of  the  signature  of  BITs  or  FTAs.  From  this  day  forward  and  from  an  institutional   perspective,  CML  began  to  undermine  their  policy  autonomy.             By   mid-­‐90s,   however,   the   Washington   Consensus   was   under   attack.   Economic   instability   in   countries   like   Mexico,   Thailand,   Russia   and   Brazil   highlighted   the   growing   uncertainty   and   risk   attached   to   this   kind   of   openness.   The   end   of   the   regime  becomes  visible  after  the  Argentina  collapse.  Unfortunately,  except  from  a   reduced  group  of  scholars  and  some  policy  makers,  few  in  the  north  become  aware   of  the  magnitude  of  the  problem.     As   the   world   experiences   its   worst   financial   crisis   for   years,   there   is   now   a   widespread   feeling   that   bold   innovations   in   global   finance   governance   are   needed.   Likewise,   policy   –   makers   worldwide   become   enthusiastic   to   undertake   a   more   pro-­‐active   regulatory   policy   towards   capital   inflows.   However,   this   return   could   ended   to   be   fragile.   On   the   one   hand,   and   despite   the   current   economic   crisis,   Wall   Street   ambitions   towards   capital   account   liberalization   on   emerging   economies   and   developing   remain   intact.   As   rules   continue   to   be   uncontested,   economic   liberalization   might   persist   to   be   legally   binding   in   some   countries   of   the   region   (i.e.:  capital  controls  could  be  contested  by  foreign  investors).  On  the  other  hand,   prudential  regulation  of  the  financial  sector  continues  to  be  under  stress.     The   paper   analyzes   the   liberalization   wave,   and   its   legal   consequences   for   developing  and  emerging  countries.  In  a  first  part,  the  paper  comments  the  macro   and   micro   consequences   observed   at   emerging   economies   when   defying   the   monetary   trilemma.   In   a   second   section,   it   looks   at   the   financial   services   institutional   transformation   launched   at   both,   multilateral   and   bilateral   level.   In   particular,   at   both   sections   it   scrutinizes   the   experiences   of   market   liberalization   and   financial   crash   suffered   by   Argentina   and   South   Korea   in   recent   years,   and   the    

4  

institutional   changes   introduced   by   both   countries   at   this   stance.   For   Argentina,   the   institutional   scheme   ended   in   crash,   the   unanswered   question   is   whether   a   comparable   institutional   transformation   could   bring   Korea   to   affront   similar   consequences  in  the  future.        

 

5  

 

2.  A  Micro  –  Macro  approach.     2.1  Macro:  The  case  for  capital  controls     The  incompatible  trinity  (or  "trilemma  ")  is  a  term  used  in  discussing  the  problems   associated   with   creating   a   stable   international   financial   system.   It   refers   to   the   impossibility   to   achieve   simultaneously   the   triple   contradicting,   but   desirable   goals   of   fixing   its   exchange   rate   (to   foster   stabilization   of   trade   and   growth),   of   running   an   independent   monetary   policy   (to   achieve   domestic   monetary   policy   goals)   and   of   freeing   completely   its   capital   flows   (for   an   optimal   allocation   of   resources).   According   to   the   Mundell-­‐Fleming   model,   a   small,   open   economy   cannot  achieve  all  three  of  these  policy  goals  at  the  same  time:  in  pursuing  any  two   of  these  goals,  a  nation  must  forgo  the  third.     Under   the   golden   standard,   the   trilemma   was   fully   operative.   Capital   flows   were   almost   unfettered   and   currencies   tied   to   gold.   Henceforth,   monetary   policy   was   absent  from  the  policy  discussion.  But,  in  the  end,  the  system  collapsed  because  it   allowed   governments   no   domestic   monetary   flexibility   and   external   shocks   were   passing   through   the   national   economy   without   further   restrictions.   The   financial   architecture   settled   down   at   the   Bretton   Woods   radically   altered   the   previous   scheme,  introducing  a  more  stable  regime  although  a  closed  one.  Currencies  were   pegged   to   the   dollar,   which   in   turn,   was   tied   to   gold.   Until   the   70s,   international   financial   markets   were   tiny   and   highly   regulated,   generalized   categorized   as   “repressed”.  Capital  controls  were  present  in  most  countries,  both  on  inflows  and   outflows5”.  At  the  beginning  of  the  seventies  the  previous  consensus  collapsed,  and   perceptions  [over  the  costs  and  benefits  of  regulate  the  capital  account]  began  to   change   drastically.   The   system   of   fixed   exchange   rates   broke   down,   and   a   new                                                                                                                   5  

Capital   controls   could   take   a   quantitative   or   qualitative   character,   affecting   inflows   and   /   or   outflows.   Among   the   regulations   affecting   capital   inflows   could   be   mentioned   those   introducing   minimum  stay  requirement  or  limiting  local  agents  (domestic  firms  and  residents)  from  borrowing   in  foreign  currencies,  or  the  introduction  of  unremunerated  reserve  requirement  (URR).  Exchange   controls   or   taxes   /   restrictions   on   outflows   could   be   cited   as   an   example   of   management   techniques   affecting   outflows.   Price-­‐based   techniques   include   the   Tobin   tax   or   the   URR,   whereas   quantitative   –   based   measures   include   quantitative   limits   on   foreign   ownership   of   domestic   companies   stock   or   reporting  requirement  and  quantitative  limits  on  borrowing  from  abroad.    

 

6  

market-­‐friendly  era  began.  A  true  crusade  against  financial  regulation  and  capital   controls  unleashed,  and  monetary  authorities  at  developing  countries  were  seen  as   the   territory   to   conquest6.   Financial   services   also   advanced   in   that   direction,   and   liberalization  and  deregulation  transformed  the  banking  industry.     Exceptions,   however,   remained   important   among   countries   and   regions   alike.   In   particular,   regarding   the   opportunity   and   degree   of   capital   account   opening,   or   with  respect  to  the  exchange  rate  system  to  be  followed7.         One  of  the  main  problems  caused  by  uncontrolled  capital  movements  is  their  effect   on   the   real   exchange   rate.   A   surge   of   capital   inflows,   especially   short   term,   can   cause  the  domestic  currency  to  appreciate8.  The  monetary  authority  can  mitigate   this  by  introducing  sterilization  measures,  although  an  expansive  use  of  them  has   important   fiscal   costs   (Ocampo,   et.   al.;   2007)9.   Alternative,   the   government   could   neutralize   currency   appreciation   by   encouraging   local   firms   to   invest   abroad   (outward  FDI)  or  by  maintaining  a  permissive  policy  towards  capital  controls,  thus   helping  investors  to  invest  abroad  (i.e.:  capital  flights).     Capital  controls  have  important  supporters,  some  new  fans  and  a  significant  group   of   (persistent)   critics10.   After   an   ostracism   of   almost   30   years,   it   seems   that   the                                                                                                                  

6   CML   (the   crusaders   motto)   was   inspired   in   neoliberal   paradigm   of   perfect   capital   markets.   This   theory  treated  economic  agents  as  being  perfectly  informed  and  fully  rational.  Markets,  on  the  other   hand,  operate  under  conditions  of  perfect  competition,  and  no  market  imperfections  exist.  In  short,   too  much  perfect!       7  In  this  sense,  several  countries  in  Asia  pegged  their  currency  with  the  dollar  in  order  to  catching   up   the   US   economy.   Asian   countries   were   also   particularly   cautious   with   respect   to   the   policy   timing,  maintaining  controls  on  the  capital  account  for  years.  Sequencing  was  as  well  important  in   deregulating  the  banking  system  at  Asian  countries,  as  nowadays  exemplifies  China.     8  

The   quantitative   easing   policy   followed   among   industrial   economies   (US),   might   be   actually   aggravating  the  problem  for  emerging  markets  and  developing  economies.   9  Sterilization  operations  might  also  result  in  additional  capital  inflows,  as  an  interest  rate  increase  

push  financial  investors  from  abroad  to  buy  local  titles.     10  The  subject  has  been  discussed  from  time  to  time,  and  particularly  after  the  arrival  of  a  financial   collapse.   Henceforth,   the   discussion   has   an   important   record   among   those   analyzing   the   Latin   American  region,  whereas  the  debate  is  more  recently  for  those  focusing  at  Asia.  There  are  plenty  of   recent  works  on  the  issue,  including  Epstein  (2009),  Gallagher  (2010),  and  Grabel  (2010).  Even  the   IMF   recently   recognized   the   case   for   capital   controls   (IMF   Technical   Note,   2010).   In   addition,   discussions   and   /   or   empirical   data   could   be   found   at   INTERNET   or   specialized   BLOGSPOT,   including   the   Econbrowser   (http://www.econbrowser.com/);   Economist   View   (http://economistsview.typepad.com/)  Triple  Crisis  blog  (http://www.triplecrisis.com/),  East  Asian   Forum   (http://www.eastasiaforum.org),   the   Bretton   Woods   Project   (http://www.brettonwoodsproject.org/index.shtml),   VOX   (http://www.voxeu.org/)   or   those  

 

7  

former  group  is  beginning  to  outweigh  the  latter  group.  The  current  situation  has   also  raised  concern  on  several  policy  makers  about  the  importance  to  re-­‐regulate   the  financial  sector11.  Henceforth,  a  brief  historical  recount  could  be  helpful.     Back  to  the  70s,  funds  become  intermediated  by  the  banking  system.  Overflowing   with   liquidity   thanks   to   large,   readily   available   deposits   (eurodollars)   and   strongly   rising   petroleum   prices   (petrodollars),   the   transnational   banks   set   out   to   find   new   clients,   mainly   in   newly   independent   and   Latin   American   Countries   (LAC).   Meanwhile,   the   historical   IMF   position   favouring   capital   controls   become   radically   altered,  notably  by  changing  its  charter  to  include  a  mandate  to  promote  CML.  At   the  same  time,  a  secular  move  toward  more  financial  deregulation  began  in  many   countries,  including  some  developing  ones.     Nonetheless,   when   the   crisis   arrived   to   the   region,   the   Bretton   Woods   financial   institutions   were   altering   their   lending   practices,   adopting   a   more   orthodox   economic   policy   stance,   which   by   the   very   nature   were   increasingly   foreign   investor-­‐friendly  ones  (Mortimore  and  Stanley,  2009).  The  IMF  did  so  primarily  by   way   of   its   Stabilization   Programs   packages   whereas   the   WB   did   so   mostly   through   Structural   Adjustment   Programs12.   The   debt   crisis   cost   LAC   a   decade   of   growth.   LAC  policy  space  was  seriously  damaged,  including  its  capacity  to  introduce  capital   controls  or  re-­‐regulate  its  financial  sector.     At  the  early  1990s  the  situation  had  changed  once  again.  Capitals  were  returning   to   the   developing   world,   particularly   under   the   form   of   portfolio   investment,   changing   the   nature   of   finance,   as   bonds   replaced   loans.   Markets   in   developed   countries  were  also  expanding,  and  new  financial  instruments  were  appearing  and   others   growing   in   importance   (Turner,   2010)13.   However,   these   new   emerging                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                       hosted   by   Newspapers   and   Journals   http://blogs.ft.com/beyond-­‐brics/)      

(for  

example,  

FT´s  

Beyond  

BRICs  

blog  

11   Take,   for   example,   the   Financial   Stability   Forum   (FSF).   These   forum   recommendations   are   directed   to   update   the   regulation   of   the   banking   industry   but   also   working   on   other   sensible   financial  (as  those  related  to  accounting  standards  and  credit  rationing  agencies).   12   These   institutions   often   utilized   cross-­‐conditionality   in   their   programs   and   sometimes   in   coordination  with  regional  development  banks.     13   A   huge   market   in   interest   rates   derivatives   grown   from   almost   zero   in   1987   to   over   $   400   trillion  

in   2007.   Similarly,   global   credit   derivative   contracts   (GCDCs)   and   collateralized   debt   obligations   (CDOs)   grew   from   zero   in   the   mid   1990s   to   over   $   60   trillion   (2007)   and   $   250   billion   (2005).  

 

8  

markets   were   not   exempted   from   bust   and   crisis,   to   finally   break   apart.   Starting   at   Mexico   (1994),   financial   crisis   will   later   spread   through   Southern   Asia   (South   Korea,   at   1997),   arriving   at   Russia   (August,   1998),   Brazil   (January,   1999),   and   Turkey  (February,  2001).  The  “financial  -­‐  crash  world  tour”  would  finally  arrive  to   Argentina,   at   December   2001.   However,   policy   advisors   and   most   academic   pundits   found   no   relationship   between   propensity   to   financial   crisis   and   openness   to  foreign  capital  flows14.  Although  they  failed,  market  pressure  and  international   financial   institutions   maintained   this   principle   in   practice   (Ocampo,   2010),   and   capital  controls  did  not  return  (Walter,  2006).  Take  by  case  the  position  adopted  at   the   IMF   Hong   Kong   meeting   in   1997,   at   the   midst   of   the   Asian   crisis,   asking   member   countries   to   made   capital   account   liberalization   a   binding   commitment   (Bhagwati,  1998;  Turner,  2010).     The   following   paragraphs   introduce   the   experiences   of   Argentina   and   the   Korea   Republic,   including   the   main   policy   response   introduced   by   authorities   in   both   countries  in  the  aftermath  of  the  crises.    

2.2  IMF  lesson  1:  Argentina     Until   the   mid-­‐1970s   Argentina   followed   a   strategy   of   import   substitution   industrialization  (ISI).  Between  1964  and  1974  GDP  grew  by  an  average  of  4,4%,   whereas   industrial   production   increased   at   6,7%.   Under   the   ISI   model   the   state   became   an   important   economic   actor,   including   its   leading   role   in   the   financial   front  through  the  fixing  of  interest  rates  and  by  rationing  resources  to  (selected)   investors   (or   projects)15.   Capital   inflows   and   outflows   were   strictly   limited,   including   important   restrictions   on   remittances   and   limitations   in   foreign   exchange   transactions.   Notwithstanding,   in   1975   the   country   suffered   a   huge                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                      

Finally,   it   should   be   also   be   noted   the   immense   growth   of   commodities   futures   trading   (Turner,   2010).       14   Others   authors,   however,   adverted   from   the   fragility   of   the   situation   and   the   high   correlation   observed   between   financial   liberalization   and   the   probability   of   suffering   a   financial   crisis   augmented   (Kaminsky   and   Reinhart,   1999;   Eichengreen   and   Bordo,   2001).   Certainly,   the   likelihood   amplified   when   liberalization   is   coupled   with   deregulation   of   the   domestic   banking   sector   (Kaminsky  and  Reinhart,  1999,  Eichengreen,  2010).       15   As   bank   reserve   requirement   were   generally   settled   at   very   high   levels,   bank-­‐lending   capacity   was  limited.    

 

9  

macroeconomic   crisis,   making   clear   the   incapability   of   the   model   to   increase   productivity   and,   henceforth,   to   maintain   the   country   competitiveness.   This   discouraging  evolution  in  competitiveness,  in  turn,  resulted  in  recurrent  balance-­‐ of-­‐payments   crises   and   stop-­‐and-­‐go   cycles   determined   by   the   availability   of   foreign   exchange,   generating   increasing   inflation   and   macro   instability.   For   authors   like   McKinnon   or   Shaw,   financial   repression   (FR)   was   among   the   main   culprits  for  the  persisting  macroeconomic  distress16.  The  idea  seduced  the  military   elite   around   the   time   of   the   coup   d´etat.   Henceforth,   in   order   to   curb   the   vast   macroeconomic   dilemma,   the   dictatorship   launched   an   ambitious   liberalization   package,   a   shock   therapy   directed   to   remove   (or   reduce)   the   number   of   controls   over  the  economy,  including  the  reduction  of  trade  barriers,  the  gradual  removal  of   capital   controls   and   the   freeing   of   interest   rates.   Financial   liberalization,   in   turn,   was   accompanied   by   the   passing   of   the   Financial   Entities   Law,   in   1977,   whereby   financial   institutions   were   allowed   to   organize   themselves   as   universal   banks.   A   new  stabilization  program  was  also  put  in  place,  introducing  a  new  exchange  rate   regime:   a   preannounced   rate   of   crawl   (the   “tablita”).   The   program   captivated,   in   particular,   financial   investors,   as   it   promised   important   and   (apparently)   safe   returns17.   The   credibility   of   the   economic   program,   however,   become   under   stress   after   the   Central   Bank   of   Argentina   was   forced   to   rescue   of   several   banks   from   systematic   failure   in   March   1980.   Problems   aggravated   soon   after   when   the   monetary   authority   became   required   to   finance   the   public   sector   deficit.   Consequently,   and   in   order   to   seduce   investors,   the   government   raised   interest   rates   on   peso   deposits18.   An   opportunity   for   arbitrage   was   evident,   marking   the   beginning   of   the   end   for   the   neoliberal   experiment.   At   early   1981,   a   balance   of   payment  crisis  marked  the  end  for  the  dictatorship  duple  Videla  –  Martinez  de  Hoz.                                                                                                                     16  

By   leaving   interest   rate   at   market   forces,   the   economy   would   automatically   adjust   to   the   equilibrium  levels,  and  henceforth,  a  more  efficient  allocation  is  obtained.  The  economy  is  thought   to   perform   under   a   Wiksellian   framework,   were   savings   equals   investments,   and   interest   rates   movements   only   affects   savings   decisions   via   the   substitution   effect.   But,   in   real   world   saving   decisions  are  also  income  and  wealth  effects.  The  approach  also  misses  the  role  played  by  liquidity   constraints   under   financial   repression,   and   the   fact   that   financial   liberalization   may   stimulate   consumption  rather  than  savings.     17   The   new   legislation   passed   by   the   government   in   1977   allowed   banks   to   accept   deposits   from  

non-­‐residents  denominated  in  foreign  currencies.  Originally  investors  were  obliged  to  kept  deposits   for  a  year,  although  the  requirement  was  later  relaxed  until  its  abandonment  in  1979.       18   By   the   end   of   1980   the   interest   differential   adjusted   for   announced   depreciation   was   approximately  3%  per  month    

 

10  

At  the  aftermath  of  the  crisis,  the  Argentina  economy  reversed  prior  liberalization   measures,   reintroducing   several   controls   previously   dismantled,   including   those   affecting   the   capital   account.   Nevertheless,   been   harshly   constrained   by   the   external   debt   and   low   commodity   prices,   the   Argentinean   economy   failed   to   recover19.  In  the  spring  of  1989,  inflation  spiraled  out  of  control,  and  President  R.   Alfonsín   was   forced   to   resign   six   month   ahead   of   schedule.   The   launch   of   the   convertibility   plan   in   March   1991,   introducing   a   fixed   one-­‐to-­‐one   dollar-­‐peso   exchange   rate,   enabled   Menem’s   Government   to   stabilize   the   economy   after   the   chaos   that   followed   the   debt   crisis,20.   Dollarization   of   the   local   economy   become   highly  encouraged  by  the  national  government,  by  making  legally  feasible  to  write   contracts   in   foreign   currencies   and   allowing   foreign   currencies   to   be   used   as   an   alternative  means  of  payments.  More  or  less  simultaneously,  Argentina  embarked   in  a  process  of  trade  deregulation  and  liberalization,  reducing  tariffs  significantly   and   dismantling   practically   all   barriers.   Likewise,   authorities   lifted   almost   all   previous   restrictions   on   international   investments,   including   those   banning   or   limiting  foreign  participation  in  key  economical  sectors21.  Financial  markets  were   liberalized  and  deregulated,  and  former  restrictions  on  the  entry  of  foreign  banks   were  raised.     Privatizations   soon   became   one   of   the   pillars   of   the   new   economic   programme,   enabling   the   government   to   reduce   its   external   debt,   remove   the   financial   liabilities   generated   by   public   utilities   from   the   public   sphere,   and   last,   but   not   least,   attract   fresh   FDI22.   Argentina’s   macroeconomic   performance   improved   notably   and   the   country   entered   into   a   solid   upward   spiral   of   growth,   with   the   national   economy   expanding   by   around   9%   per   year   in   1994.   Foreign   direct                                                                                                                   19   During   the   period   1981-­‐89,   average   real   GDP   growth   was   negative   at   -­‐0,7   percent,   and   real   income  in  1989  had  slid  to  90  percent  of  its  1980  level.     20  The  plan  required  the  monetary  base  to  be  backed  with  international  reserves  (2/3)  and  dollar-­‐

denominated  Argentina  central  bank  securities  at  market  prices  (1/3).  Argentina’s  Central  Bank  was   effectively   converted   into   a   currency   board   that   could   only   issue   domestic   currency   in   exchange   for   foreign  currency  at  a  fixed  rate.     21  

In   1994,   the   country   granted   foreign   investors   the   national   treatment   status,   including   those   participating  at  the  financial  sector.     22  Privatization  revenues,  on  the  other  hand,  postponed  the  resolution  of  the  historical  low  saving   rate   of   the   Argentina.   The   problem   will   become   more   accurate   at   the   end   of   the   nineties,   when   public   deficits   began   to   increase   pari   passu   with   foreign   investors   demands   of   greater   fiscal   discipline.      

 

11  

investment   began   to   arrive   at   the   country,   particularly   directing   at   the   utilities   sector  (gas,  electricity,  telecommunications)23.   However,   the   exposure   of   the   economy   to   international   capital   flows   volatility   remained   immense,   at   the   same   time   that   the   space   for   policy   options   was   sinking24.   And,   unfortunately,   the   Tequila   crisis   arrived.   The   economy   slumped,   with   gross   domestic   product   falling   by   2,8   percent   in   1995.   The   financial   sector   was  particularly  affected  as  bank  deposits  plunged  by  18%  in  less  than  five  months   (from   20-­‐12-­‐1994   to   12-­‐5-­‐1995),   forcing   monetary   authorities   to   assist   financial   entities  in  problems25.  Fortunately,  the  government  obtained  additional  financing   from   official   and   private   sources,   plus   the   assistance   from   IFIs.   In   order   to   maintain   the   credibility   on   the   system,   authorities   undertook   several   actions,   including  the  introduction  of  new  legislation  and  further  encouraging  the  arrival  of   foreign   entities26.   Accordingly,   whereas   in   1994   only   15%   of   total   Argentine   banking   system   assets   was   held   in   foreign   banks,   its   market   share   increased   to   55%   in   1998   and   73%   in   2000   (De   la   Torre,   Levy   Yeyati   and   Schmukler,   2003),   denationalization   process   that   coincided   with   an   accelerating   process   of   banking   concentration   (Damill,   et.al.,   2010)27.   In   order   to   keep   the   Convertibility   alive   Menem  and  Cavallo  played  tough  enough,  allowing  interest  rates  to  increase  up  to   40%   and   raising   (unpopular)   taxes   (basically,   VAT   rate   from   18   to   21   percent).   They   demonstrated   their   commitment   to   the   model   and   to   the   economy   orthodoxy,   and   (temporarily)   succeeded   (Blustein,   2005).   Contentedly   the   challenge   becomes   quickly   overcome,   and   the   economy   recovered   in   1996.   Henceforth,   Argentina   became   a   showcase   of   successful   reform   in   LAC   and   President  Menem  was  hailed  as  an  example  to  follow  in  the  1998  annual  meeting                                                                                                                   23  A  second  boom  of  FDI  took  place  at  1997-­‐99  period,  when  a  much  large  fraction  of  Argentinean  

assets  where  sold  to  foreign  residents,  including  the  privatization  of  YPF,  the  former  state-­‐owned,   company  at  the  oil  and  gas  market.     24   Sterilization   operations   were   reduced   whereas   former   controls   on   the   capital   account   were   completely   lifted.   Henceforth,   the   government   become   prisoner   of   investors´   mood   and   obliged   to   constantly  seduce  them  (reputational  game).     25  The  convertibility  eliminated  Central  Bank  role  as  lender  of  last  resort   26  

The   government   have   previously   modified   the   Law   of   Financial   Entities   granting   national   treatment  to  foreign  banks  and  removing  a  former  ban  on  market  entrance  (Damill,  et.al.,  2010).   27   As   a   consequence   of   the   Tequila,   financial   entities   in   operation   reduced   from   205   to   158,   being   106  at  2001.      

 

12  

of  the  IMF  and  World  Bank  in  Washington28.  Thinks  were  not  equal,  however,  after   a   new   series   of   financial   crises   broke   out   in   1998.   Thereafter   the   Argentine   economy   slipped   into   a   downward   spiral   towards   depression   and   crisis.   A   year   later,   Argentinean   GDP   experienced   a   3,4%   plunged,   mostly   driven   by   an   impressive  fall  in  investment  (13,6%).  Decreasing  consumption,  on  the  other  hand,   relapse   trade   balance   deficits   as   imports   almost   collapsed.   But   public   debt   keeps   increasing   (surpassing   the   $   100   billion   barrier   in   1999),   and   foreign   investors   began   to   carefully   observe   the   Argentinean   fiscal   deficit.   As   the   government   offered  higher  yields,  however,  they  kept  on  buying  Argentinean  bonds29.  Once  the   new  elected  government  of  De  la  Rua  took  office  in  December  1999  recession  was   installed.   Nevertheless,   investing   banks   and   rating   agencies   maintained   their   “interest”   in   the   country,   continuing   the   selling   of   Argentinean   bonds   all   around   the  world,  particularly  among  less  informed  investors  in  Europe  and  Japan30,31.  In   order  to  keep  alive  the  convertibility  plan,  the  government  also  obtained  in  a  trial   to   shield   the   convertibility   and   revert   foreign   investors   mood,   the   government   agreed   a   three-­‐year   standby   arrangement   for   $   7,2   billion   in   March   2000,   augmented   by   $   13,7   billion   at   January   2001.   The   bailout   agreement   (the   “blindaje”)   was   an   initiative   commonly   introduced   by   the   Fund   in   order   to   assist   emerging   countries   at   financial   distress32.   In   September   2001,   the   IMF   loan   was  

                                                                                                                28   As   exemplified   by   the   enthusiastically   words   pronounced   by   the   former   IMF   Director   Michael   Camdeessus  at  the  occasion  “[I]n  many  respects  the  experience  of  Argentina  in  recent  years  has  been   exemplary,   including   in   particular   the   adoption   of   the   proper   strategy   at   the   beginning   of   the   1990s   and   the   very   courageous   adaptation   of   it   when   the   tequila   crisis   put   the   overall   subcontinent   at   risk   of   major   turmoil…   [S]o   clearly,   Argentina   has   a   story   to   tell   the   world:   a   story   which   is   about   the   importance  of  fiscal  discipline,  of  structural  change,  and  of  monetary  policy  rigorously  maintained”.     29  Higher  interest  rates  reflected,  in  turn,  pessimistic  perceptions  from  investors  or  higher  country-­‐ risk     (“riesgo   país”).   As   documented   at   Blustein   (2005),   the   influence   of   both,   investment   banks   and   rating  agencies,  in  attracting  foreign  investors  was  superb.  Certainly,  those  actors  were  not  forcing   Argentine  authorities  to  avoid  a  prudent  fiscal  policy.         30  

Syndicated   investment   banks   tailored   a   number   of   their   offering   to   Europe   attracted   by   regulatory   leaks,   and   small   investors   appetite   for   higher   yields   (Blustein,   2005).   Consequently,   Italian  retail  investors  were  among  those  convinced  to  sue  Argentine  at  the  (international)  tribunals   to  claim  for  the  full  payment  of  their  bonds.       31  

From   January   to   September   2000,   the   Argentine   government   borrowed   nearly   $   6   billion   by   selling  dollar-­‐denominated  bonds,  at  interest  rate  from  11  3/8  per  cent  to  12  per  cent.  It  borrowed   another  $  4  billion  –  plus  by  selling  euro  denominated  bonds,  mostly  to  European  retail  investors,   paying  annual  interest  of  8  1/8  per  cent  to  10  ¼  per  cent  (Blustein,  2005).     32  By  fixing  the  loan  at  U$  14  billion,  the  bank  surpassed  in  excess  Argentine’s  lending  limits.    

 

13  

newly  extended  up  to  $  22  billion  from  which,  $  3  billion  were  used  in  support  of  a   possible  debt-­‐restructuring  operation   Macroeconomic  perceptions  in  local  businessman  plunged  and  unemployment  and   social   indicators   worsened   as   the   new   economic   team   preferred   to   reassure   foreign   investors   expectations   by   introducing   a   tightening   fiscal   policy.   But   the   new   package   did   not   help   in   reversing   pessimistic   perceptions   from   economic   agents,  condemning  the  convertibility  to  fall.  In  a  latest  attempt  to  rescue  the  plan   and   impede   massive   capital   outflows   and   a   generalized   run   on   banks,   the   government   introduce   financial   controls   (termed   the   “Corralito”   or   little   corral”).   Likewise,  foreign  currency  transactions  were  prohibited  preventing  both,  local  and   foreign   investors   to   transfers   funds   abroad.   A   month   later,   in   January   2002,   the   peso  was  officially  devalued,  and  all  the  bank  deposits  and  debts  were  converted  in   pesos33.     The   local   economy   began   its   recuperation   thereafter,   to   great   extent,   thanks   to   the   instauration  of  a  competitive  exchange  rate  policy.    During  the  2003-­‐2009  period,   Argentinean  GDP  grow  at  a  rate  of  8,5%.  Previous  liberalization  measures  on  the   capital   account   were   phased   out,   as   the   government   introduce   several   controls   following   the   crisis34.   In   particular,   and   following   the   2001-­‐02   crisis,   the   Central   Bank   of   Argentina   (BCRA)   introduced   a   90   days   residence   requirement   [to   be   further   extended   up   to   1-­‐year   residence   period]35   and   a   30%   tax   on   incoming   funds.   Restrictions   were   also   affecting   commercial   operations;   as   importers   currencies   requirements   required   BCRA   approval   whereas   exporters   become   obliged  to  vend  their  currencies  earnings  to  the  BCRA.         Capital   controls   began   to   be   relaxed   by   the   end   of   2002,   but   resumed   when   the   latest   crisis   made   its   arrival.   After   private   enterprises   began   to   flight   capitals  

                                                                                                               

33  Dollar  deposits  were  converted  at  1,4  pesos  to  the  dollar,  while  dollar  loans  were  subject  to  one-­‐

to-­‐one  conversions.     34  As  Argentina  maintained  its  capital  account  open  until  the  latest  days  of  the  convertibility  scheme,  

outflows   of   capital   augmented   during   200-­‐01   ($   23   billions   left   the   country   in   that   period).   Controls   were  reintroduced  at  December  2001,  but  funds  poured  out  throughout  the  stock  market  channel.     35  BCRA  A/3712  September  2002.  It  would  be  extended  to  180  days  one  year  later  (BCRA  A/3972),   and  up  to  1  year  (BCRA  A/4359).  

 

14  

responding   to   increasing   political   turmoil   and   increasing   macro   instability,   the   government  reintroduced  some  policy  measures  in  order  to  block  capital  outflows.  

2.3  IMF  lesson  2:  South  Korea     Since   the   early   1960s   to   last   eighties   Korea   economic   policy   was   inspired   by   a   export-­‐led   growth   model.   From   the   time   when   General   Park   launched   its   wide-­‐ ranged  economic  reform  in  1963  to  year  1997,  the  real  per  capita  income  growth   averaged   more   than   6%   annually.   On   the   whole,   the   Southern   Korean   miracle   rested  on  a  particular  mix  of  market  incentives  and  state  direction,  together  with  a   highly  repressed  financial  market  (Amsden,  1994;  Chang,  2008).     Domestic  savings  (plus  international  aid)  financed  capital  accumulation  during  this   period,   whereas   capital   inflows   either   in   the   form   of   portfolio   investment   or   FDI   were   not   in   attendance.   Industrial   policy   guided   financial   system   behaviour,   and   (national)   banks   funds   were   basically   directed   to   the   productive   sector36.   Loans   were   mainly   allocated   according   to   the   government   choice   and   its   policy   goals,   facilitating   the   expansion   of   large   business   conglomerates.   As   occurred   in   many   Asian   countries,   and   after   a   brief   experiment   with   floating,   the   Korean   won   was   pegged  to  the  dollar,  and  it  would  remain  so  until  198037.  Likewise,  international   capital   flows   were   highly   controlled   and   financial   repression   widely   extended   (Noland,  2005).  Controls  were  present  in  several  sectors,  including  a  broad  range   of  areas  from  foreign  exchange  and  strict  restrictions  were  also  imposed  on  FDI  if   not   directly   banned   –   similarly,   outward   FDI   required   official   approval   and   was   subject   to   strict   regulations.   Trade   policy   was   also   under   government   scrutiny,  

                                                                                                                36  General  Parker  Lee  launched  the  development  project  in  the  early  1960s.  Under  this  regime,  the   government-­‐channelled  funds  to  those  firms  that  had  succeeded  in  exporting  its  goods  –  originally,   light   manufacturing   goods   such   as   textile   and   apparel   and   footwear.   A   decade   later,   South   Korean   government   introduced   the   Heavy   and   Chemical   Industry   Promotion   Plan   (HCIP),   targeting   6   heavy   manufacturing   industries   for   development.   The   plan   favored   the   creation   of   large   business   conglomerates  (Chaebols).     37   For   example,   Japan   pegged   its   currency   at   360   per   dollar   for   two   decades.   In   February   1980,   South  Korea  moved  off  a  strict  dollar  peg  and  began  to  peg  the  won  to  a  basket  of  currencies  that   constituted   the   Special   Drawing   Right   plus   a   policy   adjustment   factor.   Thereafter,   the   currency   depreciated  against  all  currencies  in  the  basket.    

 

15  

particularly  on  the  imports  side38.  The  local  currency  was  nonconvertible  and,  as   experienced   by   other   developing   countries,   the   Korean   government   also   discouraged   any   offshore   market   in   won   or   won-­‐denominated   instruments.   Current   accounts   were   also   firmly   controlled   by   the   government   and   strict   exchange  restrictions  were  applied  to  all  capital  outflows  till  the  1980s.     Liberalization,   nevertheless,   began   to   gain   momentum   in   the   late   1980s   to   be   finally   adopted   in   the   1990s39.   At   the   aftermath   of   the   1997   financial   crisis,   henceforth,  Korea  Republic  turned  definitively  into  the  neoliberal  path40.  The  Kim   Dae-­‐Jung   government   accepted   the   mainstream   view   and   implemented   the   restructuring   programme   suggested   by   the   IMF   (Turner,   2010;   Lee,   2010)   and,   unquestionably,   deeply   backed   by   the   US   government   (Crotty   and   Lee,   2005)41.   The  financial  sector  was  at  the  centre  of  the  changes  to  the  economic  system,  as  the   government   indentified   financial   repression   and   industrial   conglomerates   -­‐   chaebol   corporate   governance   as   the   culprit   of   the   crisis42.   Henceforth,   Korean   authorities   adopted   a   profound   liberalization   package   after   the   crisis,   implying   more   deregulation   and   privatization.   Likewise,   the   government   raised   the   short-­‐ term   interest   rate   along   imposing   a   restrictive   fiscal   policy   (Crotty   and   Lee,   2005),  

                                                                                                               

38   The   government   introduced   in   1978   an   import   diversification   program   (IDP),   whose   objective  

was   to   restrict   imports   from   specific   countries   but   Japan,   with   which   Korea   was   experiencing   a   serious  trade  deficit  (Cheong,  2002).     39   In   adopting   the   package,   pressure   from   the   US   was   important,   certainly.   But,   Korea   interest   to  

joint  the  OCDE  also  pushed  in  the  same  direction.   40  Certainly,  the  arrival  of  General  Chun  in  1979  marked  a  turning  point  in  South  Korean  economic   policy.  In  this  sense,  the  new  government  launched  a  financial  liberalization  package  in  1982.  But,   financial  repression  and  capital  controls  were  maintained.  Foreign  participation  in  financial  markets   and  domestic  firms´  access  to  foreign  capital  continued  to  be  limited.  Likewise,  alternative  sources   of  corporate  finance  were  suppressed  (Nolan,  2005).       41   “The   IMF´s   major   shareholder   governments   made   no   secret   of   their   view   that   IMF   assistance   should   be   accompanied   by   strong   reforms.   The   U.S.   authorities   in   particular   insisted   that   strong   reforms  should  be  a  condition  of  IMF  support”  (IMF,  2003,  p.  185,  quoted  at  Crotty  and  Lee,  2005).     42   The   1980s   financial   deregulation   implied   the   expansion   of   the   non-­‐bank   financial   institutions  

(NBFIs),   financial   entities   mainly   dominated   by   the   chaebols.   NBFIs   grew   rapidly,   intensifying   the   financial   power   of   the   conglomerates   that,   in   turn,   were   profiting   from   more   freedom   in   investment   and   financing   (Lee,   2010).   During   1996-­‐97,   an   important   number   of   firms   enter   into   bankruptcy   (including,  among  others,  Hanbo  Steel  and  Kia  Motors),  and  dragging  their  lenders  with  them  (as,  for   example,   Seoul   Bank   and   Korea   First   Bank)   (Sohn,   2002).   In   the   aftermath   of   the   crisis,   Chaebols   were   coerced   to   merge,   strategy   that   become   know   as   the   “big   deal”.   In   exchange   they   received   extensive  tax  benefits  and  financial  support  (Amsden,  2001).    

 

16  

certainly   in   tandem   with   a   traditional   IMF   discourse43.   Macroeconomic   numbers   were,   unquestionably,   in   that   direction,   with   year   1998   to   be   considered   as   the   worst   in   Korean   economic   history   (Lee,   2010),   GDP   plunged   6,9%   whereas   consumption   reduced   a   10,6%.   IMF   recessive   policies   were   suffered   the   most   by   the   corporate   sector,   as   credit   crunch   left   Korean   firms   with   lesser   funds.   As   a   result,   corporate   investment   collapsed   in   1998,   and   fixed   investment   shrank   by   more   than   twenty   per   cent   (Lee,   2010)44.   Henceforward,   Korea   initiated   a   new   macro   trend,   where   investments   become   less   relevant   and   private   consumption   incentivised45.   The  government  went  further  from  the  IMF  package,  deepening  the  original  trade   liberalization   programme46.   In   terms   of   investments   and   business   environment,   foreign   investors   were   among   the   most   benefited   (Noland,   2005;   Lee,   2010)47.   FDI   deregulation  continued  its  pace,  and  the  1998  Foreign  Investment  Promotion  Act   removed   many   of   the   former   restrictions48,   including   cross   –   border   M&A   operations.   Similarly,   restrictions   on   remittances   were   completely   lifted   under   the   new   legislation,   guaranteeing   foreign   investors   legally   and   unconditional   transfers   of  funds,  even  under  circumstances  of  exogenous  shocks  (Sohn,  et.al.;  2002).    

                                                                                                               

43  At  the  2008  crisis,  in  contrast,  the  government  conducted  an  aggressive  expansionary  fiscal  policy  

–  including  a  generous  stimulus  package  (Kim,  undated).     44   The   fall   in   gross   investment   ascended   to   22,9%.   The   low   investment   ratio   persisted   even   after   the   2004  recovery.  Although  firm’s  cash  flows  were  recovering  fasts,  Korean  bosses  paid  their  debts  and   maintained  liquid.       45  From  a  35-­‐40%  range  in  the  1990-­‐97  period  in  1990-­‐97,  gross  investment  descended  to  25-­‐31%  

thereafter  (Crotty  and  Lee,  2005).     46  

Liberalization   was   undertaken   in   two   rounds.   Under   the   first   the   government   eliminated   subsidies   and   the   import   diversification   program   (IDP),   reduced   the   number   of   items   subject   to   adjustment   tariffs,   revised   import   procedures   and   (partial)   liberalized   the   services   sector.   At   the   second  round,  the  focus  was  on  reducing  regulations  on  trade  (Sohn  et.al.,  2002).     47   As   for   example,   increasing   the   foreign   ownership   ceiling   in   Korean   companies   up   to   55%   (December,   1997),   to   finally   fully   liberalize   it   (May,   1998).   Likewise,   the   government   lifted   previous   regulations  on  corporate  bonds.     48  At  September  2001,  some  1029  business  areas  were  entirely  open  to  foreign  investment  with  only  

8  business  areas  partially  open  (primary  industry  (rice  and  barley;  beef  cattle  framing,  and  fishery);   wholesaling   of   meet;   publication   of   newspapers   and   periodicals;   energy   industry;   maritime   transportation;  air  transportation;  telecommunications;  and  specially  chartered  banks  such  export-­‐ import  banks)  and  2  areas  entirely  closed  (radio  and  TV  and  broadcasting)  to  foreign  investors.  A   year   later,   around   99,8%   of   all   business   sectors   were   open   to   foreign   investments   (Sohn,   et.al.,   2002).    

 

17  

Following   the   reforms   the   government   allowed   long-­‐term   deposits   by   non-­‐ residents  in  domestic  financial  institutions,  further  deregulation  of  domestic  firms´   short-­‐term   borrowing,   partial   deregulation   of   real   estate   investment   abroad,   along   accepting  foreign  currency  transactions  by  all  financial  institutions  and  individuals   (Lee,  2010).  Liberalization  measures  in  the  M&A  front  along  lower  asset  prices  and   depreciation   of   the   won   encouraged   foreign   companies   to   enter   in   the   Korean   market  (Sohn,  et.al.,  2002;  Lee,  2010).  Furthermore,  and  as  observed  at  Argentina   in   the   aftermath   of   the   Tequila   crisis   two   years   before,   South   Korean   monetary   authorities   encouraged   the   entry   of   foreign   banks   in   order   to   give   a   boost   to   the   national   financial   system.   Either   by   acquiring   or   by   equity   participation,   foreign   capital  invested  directly  in  the  Korean  banking  industry  (Lee,  2010)49.   The   economic   performance,   however,   was   rather   unsatisfactory   since   reforms   become  implemented  (Crotty  and  Lee,  2001;  2006)  but  recovering  with  the  arrival   of  the  new  millennium.  Liberalization  of  the  capital  and  foreign  exchange  markets   increased   foreign   capital   inflows   into   the   economy   thereafter,   but   at   the   price   of   rising   volatility   and   macro   inconsistencies.     Under   this   new   scenario   credits   become   redirected   towards   consumption   (Nolan,   2005;   Lee,   2010).   As   capital   account   liberalization   led   to   won   appreciation,   on   the   other   hand,   and   the   government   forced   domestic   financial   institutions   to   purchase   monetary   stabilization   bonds   (MSBs)   in   order   to   sterilize   inflows50.   Open   market   operations,   in  turn,  increased  the  Bank  of  Korea  vulnerability  to  interest  rate  differences  and   exchange   rate   fluctuations   (Kim,   et.al.;   2008).   In   order   to   impede   exchange   rate   from  appreciation  is  Korean  authorities  introduced  a  set  of  measures  encouraging  

                                                                                                               

49  The  foreigners´  share  in  the  banking  industry  passed  from  16,4%  in  1997  to  50,2%  in  2003,  and   57,8%  in  2007,  a  share  similar  to  those  experienced  at  Latin  American  countries.  Three  of  the  top   ten  foreign  banks  operating  in  Korea  at  2006  were  from  the  US,  controlling  25%  of  the  commercial   banking  market.  Citigroup  is  one  of  the  leading  players  in  the  market  (USITC,  2010).     50   MSBs   returns,   however,   were   highly   costly   for   the   government   (Kim,   et.   al.,   2008).   A   variable   deposit   requirement   (VDR)   on   capital   inflows   was   an   alternative.   Despite   to   be   a   controversial   instrument,   and   potentially   challenged   by   foreign   investors,   it   become   explicitly   authorized   under   the  Foreign  Exchange  Act  of  1999  (Noland,  2005).  

 

18  

capital   outflows51.   Conditions   were   also   mature   enough   as   to   inflate   a   bubble   affecting  the  real  estate  market.   After   2006,   however,   capital   flows   turned   negative,   including   the   balance   of   portfolio  investments  as  foreigners  decide  to  go  short  on  their  investments  (BOK,   2009;   Lee,   2010)52.   But,   in   order   to   suppress   real   estate   price   increases   the   BOK   maintained   its   differential   interest   rate   differential   maintained.   Henceforth,   the   Korean   banking   system   continued   to   attract   massive   funds   from   abroad   and   capital   account   remained   positive.53   The   subprime   crisis   produced   an   abruptly   change   of   expectation   in   investors.   The   banking   sector   suffered   from   de-­‐leverage   as  it  was  not  able  to  roll-­‐over  its  short  term  debt  (Kim,  undated).  Expectations  on   exchange   rate   appreciation,   on   the   other   hand,   led   foreign   investors   to   rescind   derivative  contracts  and  remain  liquid.  In  sum,  all  the  above  led  to  the  collapse  of   stock  prices  and  instability  of  the  domestic  financial  and  foreign  exchange  market   (Lee,  et.al.,  2010).     Following   Lehman   Brothers   collapse,   the   Korean   won   had   depreciated   by   over   25,4%   whereas   the   stock   price   plummeted   by   27,2%.   Nevertheless,   the   new   government   of   Lee   Myung-­‐back   continues   strongly   persuaded   with   the   new   financial-­‐led   growth   strategy   initiated   a   decade   before,   aiming   to   convert   South   Korea,   and   Seoul   in   particular,   in   the   financial   hub   of   northern   Asia.   As   it   will   be   commented   in   the   next   section,   the   Korea-­‐US   Free   Trade   Agreement   (KORUS   FTA)   is  pushing  in  the  same  direction.       But,   despite   their   advocacy   towards   financial   liberalization   and   capital   account   openness,   the   government   has   now   plans   to   (re)   introduce   controls   in   order   to   curb   capital   inflows,   including   a   withholding   tax   on   foreign   investors´   bond  

                                                                                                                51  

Measures   included   the   relaxation   of   restrictions   on   overseas   real   estate   investment,   encouragement   of   fund-­‐type   overseas   portfolio   investment,   and   deregulation   to   boost   corporate   expansions  overseas  (Kim,  et.al.,  2008).     52   Residents’   investments   abroad   in   real   estate   increased   from   U$   22   million   in   2005,   to   U$   2,7  

billion  in  2007!  Overseas  equity  investment  also  augmented  during  these  years,  but  less  spectacular:   from  U$  11  billion  to  U$  50  billion.       53  The  high  interest  rate  policy,  in  turn,  was  set  by  the  monetary  authorities  in  order  to  suppress  the   real  estate  price  increase.    

 

19  

holdings   along   further   limits   on   currency   forward   trading54   (FT,   S   Korea   Plans   capital   controls,   October   19,   2010).   Following   growing   military   tension   in   the   Korean   Peninsula   and   frightened   from   a   sudden   reversal   of   flows,   Korea   announced  its  intention  to  apply  a  levy  on  banks´  foreign  –  exchange  borrowings   (Bloomberg,  “South  Korea  Imposes  Levy  on  Foreign  Exchange  Borrowings  to  Stop   Outflows”   December   20,   2010).55   On   October,   this   year,   the   government   also   imposed   a   limit   of   250   %   of   equity   capital   on   foreign   banks   and   50   %   on   domestic   banks  to  reduce  volatility  in  capital  flows  (Bloomberg,  2010)56.     The   next   section   analyse   the   issue   from   a   micro   perspective,   including   a   critical   vision  over  the  regulatory  and  prudential  measures  affecting  the  banking  industry.    

2.4  Micro:  Beyond  Basle  regulation     The   provision   of   financial   services   has   undergone   a   transformative   expansion   in   the  last  decades,  moving  away  from  a  largely  domestic  market  to  an  increasingly   internationalized  space.  Consequently,  whereas  in  the  past  foreign  shocks  spread   into  the  host  economy  mainly  through  trade  channels  and  with  an  important  lag,   nowadays  shocks  affects  the  domestic  financial  markets  almost  immediately57.     As  capital  flows  are  canalized  throughout  the  financial  system,  transforming  flows   into   bank   liabilities   almost   instantly.   Therefore,   it   becomes   relevant   to   put   the   bank  system  into  the  picture.  As  financial  intermediaries,  on  the  other  hand,  banks   have   a   dual,   and   generally,   pro-­‐cyclical   role,   spreading   credits   (during   booms)   and                                                                                                                   54  

Yoon   Jeung-­‐hyun,   South   Korea’s   financial   minister   declarations   at   the   Parliament     “We   are   preparing   to   counter   the   potential   problems   that   liquidity   flows   into   emerging   countries   sparked   by   low  interest  rates  worldwide  can  cause”.   55  

Finance   Vice-­‐Minister   announced   the   government   intention   “to   regulate   systemic   risk   from   excessive  capital  inflows  and  outflows”,  deciding  to  introduce  a  bank  levy  to  curb  this  problem.     56   The   government   is   preparing   new   measures   in   order   to   stop   the   won   from   appreciating.   As   an   example,   it   might   be   tightening   the   cap   on   banks´   holdings   of   foreign   –   exchange   derivatives.   Furthermore,  in  order  to  tackle  speculators,  South  Korean  regulators  began  to  audit  of  how  banks   should  handle  foreign-­‐currency  derivatives.  Likewise,  on  December  8,  2010  the  National  Assembly   passed   a   bill   that   will   from   January   1st   tax   interest   income   from   treasury   and   central   bank   bonds   by   as  much  as  14%  and  put  a  20%  levy  on  capital  gains  from  their  sale.       57  The  standing  role  of  the  financial  market  appeared  after  the  collapse  of  the  Bretton  Woods  system.   Until  the  70s,  on  the  one  hand,  international  financial  markets  were  tiny  and  highly  regulated  and   capital   controls   were   worldwide   used.   On   the   other   hand,   foreign   investment   flows   were   scarce   and   capitals  arriving  to  developing  countries  were  almost  under  the  FDI  form.    

 

20  

disseminating   the   crisis   (starting   the   burst).   Financial   deregulation   coupled   with   capital   account   fully   convertibility;   certainly,   increase   the   likelihood   of   banking   crisis,   especially   when   banks   funded   themselves   on   wholesale   markets   abroad   (Eichengreen,  2010).       Regulating  cross-­‐border  transactions  becomes  imperative,  henceforth,  as  financial   globalization   has   altered   the   traditional   transmission   mechanism.   In   order   to   postpone   such   an   adjustment,   cross-­‐border   regulation   includes   reserve   requirements  on  cross-­‐border  inflows,  minimum  stay  periods  for  incoming  capital,   and   prohibition   of   certain   transactions   –e.g.,   lending   in   foreign   currencies   to   economic  agents  that  do  not  have  revenues  in  those  currencies.     Regulating  the  banking  industry  at  the  national  level  has  also  become  imperative.   Bank   supervision   and   regulation   come   into   the   sphere   of   the   Basle   Accord,   including   the   formulation   of   capital   adequacy   standards   -­‐   fixed   at   8%58.   Critics   highlighted   the   rigidity   and   simplicity   of   the   standards,   along   its   inadequacy   to   encourage   long   term   lending   and   investments   (Stalling,   2006).   Standards   would   become  later  replaced  by  new  set  market  friendly  rules,  the  Basle  II  Accord59,  by   which   regulation   become   replaced   deregulation   with   self-­‐monitoring   of   risks60.   The   new   approach   was   ill   conceived   as   it   failed   to   perceive   when   the   risk   arises   (Stalling,   2006,   Tarullo,   2008)61.   Furthermore,   the   new   capital   requirement   fixed                                                                                                                   58  The  Committee  on  Regulation  and  Supervisory  Practices  was  created  by  the  Group  of  Ten  (G-­‐10)  

at   mid-­‐seventies,   as   a   response   to   the   failure   of   HERSTATT   Bank   causing   significant   disturbances   in   currency   markets   around   the   world.   The   Committee   has   not   formal   legal   existent   or   permanent   staff,   functioning   at   the   Bank   of   International   Settlements   at   Basel,   Switzerland.   In   1975,   the   Committee   launched   its   first   paper   introducing   the   principles   for   supervisory   responsibilities   and   twelve   years   later   it   published   its   “Core   Principles   for   Effective   Banking   Supervision”   (Tarullo,   2008).         59  

Around   the   same   time,   the   US   Congress   passed   the   Gramm-­‐Bliley-­‐Leach   Act   dismantling   the   regulatory  architecture  introduced  by  the  Glass-­‐Steagall  Act  of  1933.   60   The   Basle   II   Accord   was   negotiated   between   1999   and   2004,   been   they   main   objectives   to   produce   the   rules   by   which   minimum   capital   requirements   would   be   set   under   domestic   bank   regulatory  policy  in  each  country  represented  on  the  Basle  Committee  on  Banking  Supervision.  Its   internal  rating-­‐based  approach  was  at  the  centre  of  the  new  regulation.   61    The  new  framework  is  not  only  inappropriate  for  measuring  risks  among  emerging  economies,   but   also   at   those   involving   developed   countries   financial   systems.   Tarullo   (2008)   criticize   Basle   II   approach   on   the   basis   that   it   would   not   have   been   adequate   to   contain   the   risk   exposed   by   the   subprime   crisis.   In   particular,   he   critically   assesses   the   advanced   internal   rating   based   (A-­‐IRB)   approach,   as   being   enormously   complex,   full   of   opportunities   for   bank   and   national   supervisory   discretion.    

 

21  

under  the  new  accord  reinforced  the  pro-­‐cyclical  trend  characterizing  the  former   agreement.   Advance  countries  and  emerging  market  economies  have  different  point  of  interest   from   each   other62.   Emerging   market   economies   have   special   interest   on   cross-­‐ border   flows   and   liquidity   risk   management   of   the   foreign   currency,   not   just   of   those   in   local   currency.   As   witnessed   in   the   latest   crisis,   currency   crisis   in   emerging   markets   might   begin   to   spread   by   foreign   investors   flea   one   country   after   another,   endangering   the   squeeze   in   currency   liquidity.   Thus,   for   emerging   market  economies,  the  key  task  against  external  shocks  is  to  manage  properly  the   balance   of   payment   in   a   national   dimension,   as   well   as   the   foreign   assets   and   liabilities  in  a  corporate  dimension  (Lee,  et.al.,  2010).         Analysed   countries   have   important   differences,   as   for   example   respecting   the   legal   figure   granted   to   international   banks   operating   at   Korea   and   Argentina   (foreign   branches   versus   subsidiaries).   Also   both   countries   financial   sectors   classified   as   repressed  prior  to  the  reform,  the  banking  sector  in  Argentina  characterized  for  a   more   important   presence   of   the   State,   a   larger   number   of   banks   and   a   less   concentred  market63.    Following  the  liberalization  process,  similarities  were  on  the   rise,   with   the   exception   that   State   run   banks   become   more   important   at   Korea   after  the  crisis.       The   case   of   South   Korea   comes   first.   Within   a   decade   of   interlude,   the   country   suffered  two  foreign  currency  liquidity  crises.  Before  the  crisis,  foreign  borrowing   was  the  main  channel  through  which  foreign  capital  flowed  to  the  country  as  other   transactions  were  banned.     After   the   first   crisis   the   government   fully   liberalized   capital   inflows,   including   foreign   investment   in   the   short   –   term   money   market.   Likewise,   and   with   the   objective   of   modernize   the   banking   sector,   authorities   encouraged   the   arrival   of                                                                                                                   62  

Historically,   however,   today   developed   countries   defended   the   sequencing   argument,   putting   firstly  in  the  list,  a  proper  regulatory  and  supervisory  body.     63   At   2004,   Argentina   hosted   a   total   of   206   banks   against   30   in   Korea.   The   three   largest   banks   concentrated  39,1%  of  total  deposits  in  Argentina,  whereas  in  Korea  the  market  share  of  the  three   largest  banks  was  52,8%.    

 

22  

operators   from   abroad64.   The   Foreign   Investment   Promotion   Act   of   1998   becomes   the   legal   instrument   opening   up   financial   institutions   to   foreign   investors.   A   new   wave   of   FDI   arrived   at   the   banking   industry,   now   under   the   form   of   green-­‐field   investment   and   M&A,   ending   with   a   majority   presence   in   the   industry   (Yi,   et.al.,   2009)65.  Capital  outflows  were  also  being  stimulated  by  authorities  (Nolan,  2005;   Kim  et.al.,  2008).     At   the   institutional   front,   the   government   enacted   a   new   legislation   encouraging   full-­‐scale   deregulation   in   capital   markets   (Lee,   2010)66.   Under   the   new   scheme,   domestic   investors   become   entitled   to   invest   abroad,   whereas   non   –   residents   were   also   allowed   to   make   deposits   and   open   accounts   denominated   in   Korean   won.  The  opening  of  both  the  bond  and  securities  markets  amplified  the  channels   for  capital  inflows  and  outflows67.     Financial   regulation   was   certainly   poor   when   the   1997   crisis   made   its   appearance68.   After   the   [first]   crisis,   henceforth,   the   government   began   to   push   for   strict  prudential  regulation  as  indicated  by  the  Bank  for  International  Settlements   (BIS)  (Lee,  2010)69.  Similarly,  the  government  introduced  new  regulations  in  order                                                                                                                   64   Foreign   banks   could   enter   at   the   Korean   banking   sector   in   three   different   ways:   either   through   foreign  bank  branches  making  corporate  loans,  through  running  both  its  retail  and  wholesale  level   bank   business   under   its   own   brand   name,   or   through   directly   acquiring   stock   ownership   in   the   stock  market  (Yi,  et.al.,  2009).       65  FDI  in  the  financial  sector  increased  form  $  341  million  in  1997,  to  $  2.580  in  1999,  and  to  $  1.925   in  2000.  Of  the  seven  major  domestic  banks  (Kookmin  Bank,  Woori  Bank,  Hana  Bank,  Shinhan  Bank,   Korean   Exchange   Bank,   Korean   Citi   Bank,   Standard   Chartered   First   Bank),   only   Woori   Bank   was   not   foreign  owned  at  the  end  of  2006  (Yi,  et.al.,  2009,  p.  131).     66  The  “Capital  Market  and  Financial  Investment  Services  Act”,  which  merged  six  individual  acts.  The  

new   legislation   introduced   the   negative-­‐list   approach   along   a   broader   definition   of   financial   investments.     67  Bond  market  activity  significantly  expanded  after  2003,  whereas  stock  market  capitalization  more  

than  tripled  between  2000  and  2005  (Kim  et.al.,  2008).     68  To  the  extent  that  many  authors  blamed  domestic  governance  failures  as  one  of  the  main  factors   originating  the  crisis  –  particularly  predominant  in  official  circles  in  the  developed  world.  A  similar   vision  could  be  found  at  the  IMF,  at  describing,  “financial  sector  vulnerability  was  at  the  root  of  the   Asian  crisis”.  But,  on  the  other  hand,  irresponsible  liberalization  could  be  blamed.  According  to  Yi,   Miller   and   Jeon   (2009)   since   1993   Korean   authorities   were   relaxing   controls,   in   particular,   benefiting  the  arrival  of  foreign  banks   69   In   1999,   Korean   authorities   integrated   four   supervisory   bodies   (the   Office   of   Bank   Supervision,   Securities   Supervisory   Body,   Insurance   Supervisory   Body,   and   Non-­‐bank   Supervisory   Authority)   into   a   single   new   entity   (the   Financial   Supervisory   Service).   By   the   end   of   2006,   the   New   Basel   Capital  Accord  were  passed  to  major  banks  (Kim,  et.al.,  2008).      

 

23  

to   avoid   maturity   mismatches   in   bank’s   foreign   currency   assets   and   safeguard   systems  such  as  variable  deposit  requirements  (VDR)  were  also  set  up  (Lee,  2010).     However,   and   despite   all   the   above   institutional   changes,   at   the   hike   of   the   2008   financial   turmoil   economic   agents   began   to   redirect   funds   abroad   (Lee   et.al.,   2010)70.   But,   the   problem   was   predated.   Since   2006   the   external   debt   began   to   increase   rapidly,   a   phenomenon   largely   attributed   to   loans   related   to   trading   in   derivatives   market   to   be   repaid   by   future   foreign   exchange   revenue   (Lee,   2010).   Korean  banks  were  hedging  risks  throughout  swap  operations.  But,  again,  in  order   to   make   the   funding   costs   cheaper   they   were   borrowing   USD   with   short-­‐term   maturity.   When   Lehman   Brothers   collapse,   banks   become   to   suffer   from   de-­‐ leverage.   As   a   result,   and   resembling   the   1997   crisis,   the   economy   was   suffering   from  another  currency-­‐mismatching  problem,  although  banks  were  now  the  most   affected  players71.  Thinks  gets  worse,  however,  as  most  banks  relied  on  short-­‐debt,   introducing  a  maturity  mismatch  problem  [to  the  commented,  currency  mismatch   one]   (Kim,   undated).   Henceforth,   and   overall,   the   crisis   confirmed   the   “pro-­‐ cyclicality  of  the  banking  sector.     From   a   strategic   perspective,   the   plan   to   attract   FDI   was   ill   conceived,   as   it   provided   important   incentives   (Lee,   2010),   but   few   conditions.   At   Korea,   developed   country   banks   in   particular   were   more   than   willing   to   lend   to   the   emerging  markets  countries  before  mid-­‐1997,  but  they  tended  to  do  so  in  dollars   or   yen   (often   at   short   maturities).   When   banks   withdrew   credits   and   helped   to   precipitate   the   crisis,   IMF   the   international   rescue   efforts   also   largely   ensured   that   international  banks  were  repaid  (Walter,  2006).     Argentina   2001   crisis   comes   next,   whose   financial   system   strength   served   as   an   example  to  other  emerging  economies.  To  begin  with,  it  might  be  remember  that   under  the  currency  board  the  Argentine  banking  system  was  heavily  exposed  to  a                                                                                                                  

70  As  Korea  has  achieved  perfect  FX  liberalization  both  local  and  foreigners’  investors  were  leaving   funds.   Local   investors   were   allowed   to   buy   foreign   real   estates   without   restrictions,   whereas   offshore   funds   and   overseas   funds   domiciled   in   domestic   jurisdiction   were   also   permitted   to   outbound  foreign  equity  related  investment.     71   During   2006   -­‐   I   Quarter   to   2008   -­‐   III   Quarter,   U$   168   billion   flowed   into   Korea.   From   this   total,   U$   137,4  billions  were  funded  by  the  banking  sector.  After  2008  -­‐  IV  Quarter,  and  despite  the  Korean   government  declared  a  loan  guarantee,  lenders  withdrew  from  banks  U$  59  billion  (Kim,  undated).    

 

24  

devaluation   of   the   peso   against   the   US   dollar.   This   helps   to   explain   why   the   collapse  of  the  convertibility  regime  has  become  associated  widely  with  a  dramatic   banking  crisis.     Authorities,   as   a   consequence   of   the   limited   deposit   insurance   scheme   designed   under   the   convertibility   plan,   particularly   considered   liquidity   provisions72.   Likewise,   and   in   order   to   preserve   the   solvency   of   the   financial   system,   the   government   introduced   strong   capital   requirements,   going   beyond   8%   recommended   by   the   Basle   Committee73.   The   regulatory   front   showed   several   weaknesses,   however.   The   financial   system   was   ill   equipped   to   deal   with   a   modification  in  relative  prices,  in  particular,  how  the  banks  response  should  be  to   additional  capital  requirements  posed  by  the  change.  But,  there  were  no  regulatory   alternatives  for  non-­‐tradable  producers  dealing  with  repayment  problems  related   to  exchange  rate  risk.  High  regulatory  standards  introduced  via  Basle  Accord  also   failed   to   prevent   the   excessive   risk   introduced   by   public   sector   lending   (Damill,   et.al.,   2010)74.   Argentina   needed   to   keep   its   debt   ratios   in   check,   particularly   its   debt   to   GDP   ratio.   As   the   fiscal   burden   deteriorated   exchange   risk   amplifies,   forcing   monetary   authorities   to   increase   interest   rates   in   order   to   maintain   investors´   interest75.   Consequently,   the   bank   system   became   overexposed   to   a   sovereign  default  (increasing  bank’s  solvency  problem)  and,  additionally  crowding   out  funds  from  private  agents.   After   the   Tequila   crisis,   and   following   the   massive   outflows   experienced   by   domestic   banks,   the   Menem’s   government   introduced   a   number   of   reforms   in   order   to   strength   domestic   banks   encouraging,   at   the   same   time,   the   entrance   of                                                                                                                   72  The  absence  of  an  institutional  safety  net  (i.e.:  lending  of  last  resort),  however,  becomes  one  of  the   Achilles’  heels  of  the  Argentinean  financial  system.  An  important  currency   -­‐  mismatching  problem   was  also  underestimated  along  the  system  exposure  to  a  public  sector  default  (Damill,  et.al.;  2010).     73  Argentina  adhered  to  the  1988  Basle  Accord  in  1995  and,  one  year  later,  to  its  1996  market  risk  

amendment.     74   Developed   countries   sovereign   risk   is   considered   to   be   negligible   and,   henceforth,   they   offer   lower   yielding.   However,   raising   debt   concerns   have   increased   risks   for   an   important   group   of   countries   (others   some   among   them   still   benefits   from   “club   effects”).   But,   what   really   aggravated   the  Argentinean  case  was  to  be  forced  to  borrow  in  foreign  currencies  (“the  original  sin”).  When  the   collapse  finally  arrived,  27%  of  financial  credits  were  holding  in  public  sector  pockets.     75  After  the  arrival  of  the  crisis  in  1998,  the  fiscal  burden  deteriorated  progressively,  both  at  national   and  provincial  level.  As  recession  advanced,  some  provinces  were  forced  to  introduce  cuasi-­‐money.      

 

25  

foreign  institutions.  Likewise,  Argentina  advanced  into  the  privatization  process,  in   which  the  government  got  rid  of  practically  everything  with  the  sole  exception  of   the   National   Bank   (Banco   de   la   Nación   Argentina   -­‐   BNA).   Prudential   regulations   were   also   expanded,   introducing   now   new   and   strong   “market   evaluation”   test   (colloquially   known   as   the   BASIC   system)   along   the   enforcement   of   Basle   plus   regulations76.   Following   this   set   of   policy   measures,   a   significant   process   of   mergers  and  acquisitions  took  place  in  the  industry  (Burdisso  and  D´Amato,  1999),   strongly  supported  by  the  Central  Bank  (Damill,  et.  al.,  2010).  As  a  result,  9  banks   were  holding  67%  of  all  deposits  at  year  200077,  with  2  public  institutions  leading   the  list  (BNA  and  Banco  Provincia)  (Economist.  March  4th,  2000)78.  Interest  rates   spreads,   however,   did   not   diminish   despite   the   system   gain   in   efficiency   and   foreign  banks  were  certainly  more  cautions  when  extending  credits.     When   evaluating   the   role   of   foreign   banks,   the   picture   is   more   nuanced   than   expected.  Certainly,  as  financial  risk  increased  they  began  to  reduce  their  exposure   (Dominguez  and  Tesar,  2005),  unmasking  their  proclaimed  fortress  –  in  particular,   when   looking   at   the   limited   assistance   from   headquarters   to   subsidiaries   in   distress   (Moguillansky,   et.al.,   2004;   Damill,   et.al,   2010)79.   Foreign   exchange   mismatching,   in   the   other   hand,   further   encouraged   the   interest   rate   arbitrage   benefiting  foreign  banks  the  most  as  they  confronted  lower  hedging  costs  (Damill,   et.al.,  2010)80.  Independently  of  their  origin,  banks  were  mainly  redirecting  funds                                                                                                                   76  The  government  passed  several  reforms  into  Organic  Chart  of  the  the  Central  Bank  of  Argentina   (BCRA)  including  a  new  article  in  the  financial  entities  law  (Damill,  et.al.,  2010).     77   Bank   concentration   as   measured   by   total   assets   at   the   20th   largest   banks,   passed   from   U$   23  

billion   in   1994   to   U$   80   billions   in   1998,   implying   a   significant   increase   in   their   market   share   (from   34%  to  61%).     78  Six  out  of  the  seven  followers  were  foreign  owned  banks.  Spanish  banks  were  at  the  top  of  the  list,  

reflecting   BBVA   (Banco   Francés)   and   Santader   (Banco   Río)   participation   in   the   Argentinean   financial  sector.   79   In   the   case   of   the   U.S.   legislation   establish   that   a   bank   ins   not   obliged   to   pay   deposits   made   in   a   subsidiary  abroad  if  it  is  unable  to  do  so  because:  a)  a  state  of  war,  insurrection  or  civil  revolt  exists;  or   b)   because   it   is   prevented   by   an   action   or   instrument   of   the   government   of   the   host   country,   undertaken  without  explicit  agreement  with  the  bank.  This  law  was  added  to  the  existing  legislation  in   1994,   after   Citibank   was   taken   to   court   by   depositors   in   the   Philippines   and   Vietnam   and   lost   the   respective   cases   [Section   25C   of   the   Federal   Reserve   Act,   section   326   of   the   Riegle-­‐Neal   Interstate   Banking   and   Branching   Efficiency   Act,   codified   in   12   US   Code   Section   633]   (Moguillansky,   et.   al.,   2004)     80   By   the   end   of   1998,   financial   system   external   debt   reached   U$   17,5   billion,   almost   20%   of   the   banking  sector  total  liabilities.    

 

26  

towards   private   consumption,   real   estate   mortgage   and   commercial   lending81.   Lending   to   private   agents,   however,   began   to   be   curtailed   following   the   Asian   crisis,  to  plummet  thereafter.  Banks  have  not  curtailed,  however,  their  lending  to   public  sector  entities,  despite  weaker  repayment  guarantees  (Damill,  et.al,  2010),   demonstrating   that   their   rent-­‐seeking   relationship   with   the   State   have   not   changed.   Asymmetric   pessification,   however,   exacerbated   banks   balance   sheet   problems82.     Following   the   crisis,   the   government   introduced   important   changes   in   prudential   regulation,   beginning   by   modifying   its   terms   of   adherence   to   the   1988   Basle   Accord,   reducing   the   minimum   risk-­‐weighted   regulatory   capital   coefficient   back   to   8%.     Among   other   measures   monetary   authorities   also   banned   foreign   currency   lending   to   private   agents   (except   for   those   having   incomes   in   U$).   Likewise,   it   introduced   a   ceiling   to   commercial   banks   on   their   liquidity   holdings   of   foreign   currencies.   State   owned   banks,   on   the   other   hand,   played   an   important   contra-­‐ cyclical  role,  after  the  2001  crisis.        

                                                                                                               

81   Under   the   convertibility   scheme,   certainly,   the   set   of   relative   prices   were   not   favouring   credits  

towards  the  productive  sector.     82  As  explained  by  Blustein  (2005,  p.  192-­‐3)  “To  head  off  mass  bankruptcy,  the  government  decreed  

that  most  people  who  had  borrowed  in  dollars  could  repay  their  loans  in  depreciated  pesos,  at  the  rate   of  one  peso  per  dollar.  At  the  same  time,  to  appease  savers,  the  authorities  announced  deposits  would   be   converted   at   a   different   rate   –   1.4   pesos   per   dollar.   As   a   result,   the   banking   system,   which   was   already   on   its   knees,   was   rendered   prostrate.   The   disparity   between   what   banks   could   collect   form   their  borrowers,  and  what  they  owed  their  deposits,  added  up  to  billions  of  dollars  in  new  losses….As  for   depositors,   they   felt   cheated,   notwithstanding   the   concession   the   government   had   given   them…Their   angry   reaction   lead   to   a   deepening   of   the   banking   system’s   woes,   as   thousands   of   them   obtained   court   orders   requiring   the   return   of   their   deposits   in   full,   and   money   began   draining   anew   from   the   banking   system…”.   Banks´   balance   sheets   were   also   disturbed   by   their   own   mismatching   problem,   as   they   were   forced   to   cancel   (former)   credits   in   foreign   currency   (for   example,   with   their   headquarters)   from  local  operations.      

 

27  

 

3.  An  Institutional  perspective   3.1  Liberalization  at  both  multilateral  and  bilateral     A  “regulatory  consensus”  was  floating  in  academic  circles  since  the  Bretton  Woods   Conference,   drawing   the   attention   from   policy   makers.   Likewise,   IMF   explicitly   recognized   to   member   states   the   right   to   institute   capital   controls83.   But,   the   previous   consensus   broke   up   with   the   collapse   of   the   dollar-­‐standard   in   1971,   signalling   the   beginning   of   a   new   era   of   financial   liberalization   and   market   deregulation.   Thereafter,   a   relatively   small   group   of   investor   countries,   led   by   the   USA,   took   advantage   of   the   unique   historical   events   to   implement   a   strong   push   towards   foreign   investment   liberalization,   particularly   in   developing   countries   and   economies   in   transition.   These   changes   resulted   from   the   increasing   negotiating   strength   of   the   principal   investor   countries   and   weakening   negotiating   strength   (coupled   with   greater   external   vulnerability)   of   developing   countries   and   economies   in   transition.   The   International   Financial   Institutions   (IFIs),   the   USA   and   a   few   other   investor   countries   seized   the   moment   to   dramatically   alter   the   existing   relationship   between   investor   countries   and   host   countries.   Financial   deregulation   and   capital   account   liberalization   were   part   of   the   central   message   emanated   at   Washington.   Financial   services   deregulation   becomes   one   of   the   leading   issues   for   those   representing   the   US   delegation   at   the   Uruguay   Round.   Since   the   early   1980s   American   negotiators   were   pulling   developing   nations   to   open  their  financial  markets  and  to  bring  capital  convertibility.  The  objective  was   finally  achieved  with  the  signature  of  the  GATS,  which  became  a  constitutive  part   of   the   newly   constituted   WTO   (Hoeckman   &   Kostecki,   2009).   The   agreement   included   all   internationally   –   related   services,   defining   four   ways   or   modes   of   trading   services84.   WTO   financial   commitments,   in   particular,   are   included   in   the                                                                                                                   83   According   to   IMF   [original]   Chapter   VI,   all   member   countries   had   the   right   to   control   capital   movements.     84   Usually   referred   as   modes.   Mode   1   includes   services   supplied   from   one   country   to   another.   Mode  

2   encompasses   consumers   or   firms   making   use   of   a   service   in   another   country   (officially   consumption   abroad).   Mode   3   relates   to   those   operations   involving   a   foreign   company   setting   up  

 

28  

GATS   Annexes   on   Financial   Services,   the   Second   and   Fifth   Protocols   of   the   GATS   (commonly   referred   under   the   Financial   Services   Agreement   –   FSA),   the   Understanding   on   Commitments   in   Financial   Services,   and   countries´   GATS   schedules   of   financial   services   commitments.   Specific   commitments   made   by   members   are   backed   by   national   treatment   and   market   access   clauses,   both   determining   the   liberalization   impact   of   the   agreement.   Henceforth,   and   in   contrast   to   other   international   agreements,   financial   rules   introduced   under   the   WTO   constitute   a   ceiling   (Public   Citizens,   2009),   meaning   that   once   accepted   rules   could   not   be   reversed   (Raghavan,   2009)85.   Likewise,   commitments   made   under   mode  1  (Cross-­‐border  supply)  and  mode  3  (Commercial  presence)  might  enforce   signatory  countries  to  open  its  capital  account  (Gallagher,  2010)86.     To   some   extent,   GATS   ended   to   dent   financial   regulation   at   local   level,   including   prudential   measures   aimed   to   curb   financial   crisis   propagation.   However,   some   WTO   members,   mostly   OCDE   countries,   introduced   more   liberalizing   commitments  than  requested.  As  a  result  of  this  market  –  friendly  behaviour,  some   countries   (37   over   100)   compromised   to   inhibit   themselves   in   the   use   of   capital   controls,  including  Argentina  but  not  Korea  (Gallagher,  2010,  at  page  8).  Likewise,   some  members  committed  themselves  to  a  “standstill”  rule,  meaning  that  they  are   forbidden   from   rolling   back   deregulation   (or   liberalization)   for   the   expansive   financial   services   they   commit   (TWN,   2010).   In   relation   to   the   introduction   of   prudential   regulation,   although   the   WTO   /   GATS   Annex   on   Financial   Services   contain   a   “carve   out”   provision   ensuring   that   the   agreement   will   not   undermine   domestic   law   or   regulations87.   This   guarantee   presents   several   loopholes   that                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                      

subsidiaries   or   branches   to   provide   services   in   another   country   (officially   commercial   presence).   Finally,   mode   4   includes   individuals   travelling   from   their   country   to   supply   services   in   another   (presence   of   natural   persons).   Considering   its   composition,   three   are   the   principal   elements   conforming   GATS:   a   main   text,   including   general   obligations   and   disciplines84;   annexes   dealing   with   rules   for   specific   sectors;   and   individual   countries´   specific   commitments   applying   selectively   to   each  of  the  sectors  covered  by  the  agreement   85  In  this  direction  goes  the  standstill  provision  contained  in  the  Understanding’s  Article  (A)  (Public   Citizens,  2009).   86  In  particular,  Footnote  8  at  GATS  Article  XVI  (Market  Access)  and  Article  XI  (2).  Taking  together,   these  provisions  indicate  that  a  country  making  commitments  in  the  mode  1  and  3  may  explicitly  be   required  to  open  its  capital  account.  Nevertheless,  the  author  recognizes  that  some  exceptions  may   apply.     87   “Notwithstanding   any   other   provisions   of   the   Agreement,   a   Member   shall   not   be   prevented   from  

taking   measures   for   prudential   reasons,   including   for   the   protection   of   investors,   depositors,   policy  

 

29  

ultimately  could  prevent  the  introduction  of  new  regulation  (Public  Citizen,  2009;   TWN,  2010;  Gosh,  2010)88.  Once  a  commitment  has  been  made  allowing  for  certain   kinds  of  financial  activity,  the  country  cannot  impose  any  prudential  regulation  if   they   run   counters   such   commitment.   In   other   words,   having   already   committed   to   deregulate,  a  country  cannot  easily  undo  their  legislation  (Gosh,  2010)89.     WTO  members  were  obliged  not  to  impose  restrictions  on  capital  transactions  in  a   way  inconsistent  with  the  specific  commitment  they  had  assumed  with  regard  to   such   transactions   (WTO,   2010b).   But,   as   liberalization   commitments   made   under   the  GATS/WTO  scheme  are  far  from  homogenous  (Van  Aaken  and  Kürtz,  2009),  it   continues  to  be  some  room  to  introduce  exceptionalities  or  prudential  measures  to   those   who   opted   to   preserve   their   policy   space.   Likewise,   as   commitments   followed   a   “positive   list”   approach,   further   exceptions   were   always   available.90   WTO   members   are   also   entitled   to   undertake   prudential   measures,   including   the   use  of  temporary  non-­‐discriminatory  restrictions  on  payments  and  transfers  in  the   event   of   a   serious   balance-­‐of-­‐payments   problem   and   external   financing   difficulties   (WTO,  1997)  91.     As  a  result,  capital  exporters  countries  considered  investment-­‐related  rules  settled   at   the   Uruguay   Round   suddenly   outdate.   Henceforth,   negotiators   from   developed                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                      

holders   or   persons   to   whom   a   fiduciary   duty   is   owed   by   a   financial   service   supplier,   or   to   ensure   the   integrity  and  stability  of  the  financial  system.  Where  such  measures  do  not  conform  with  the  provisions   of   the   Agreement,   they   shall   not   be   used   as   a   means   of   avoiding   the   Member’s   commitments   or   obligations  under  the  Agreement”.     88  

Prudential   measures   could   be   challenged   if   they   are   undermining   the   regulatory   constraints   otherwise   established   in   the   agreement.   The   absence   of   any   definition   for   “prudential   regulation”,   left  the  issue  subject  to  interpretation  by  WTO  dispute  resolution  panels.     89  Gosh  (2010)  exemplifies  the  point  considering  at  policies  directed  to  limit  the  size  or  total  number  

of   financial   services   suppliers   in   those   sectors   which   liberalization   commitments   have   been   made   (“covered   sectors”).   Similarly,   he   also   mention   the   limitation   a   country   have   at   banning   risky   financial  services  once  it  has  been  previously  committed.     90  In  contrast,  initiated  at  NAFTA  PTAs  launched  by  the  US  followed  a  negative  list  approach,  which   give  less  room  for  developing  countries  to  protect  their  policy  space.     91  In  particular,  countries  could  invoke  balance  of  payments  problems  following  GATS,  whose  Article  

XII  –  Paragraph  1  states  “In  the  event  of  serious  balance-­‐of  payments  and  external  financial  difficulties   or   threat   thereof,   a   Member   may   adopt   or   maintain   restrictions   on   trade   in   services   on   which   has   undertaken  specific  commitments,  including  on  payments  or  transfers  for  transactions  related  to  such   commitments.  It  is  recognized  that  particular  pressures  on  the  balance  of  payments  of  a  Member  in  the   process   of   economic   development   or   economic   transition   may   necessitate   the   use   of   restrictions   to   ensure,  inter  alia,  the  maintenance  of  a  level  of  financial  reserves  adequate  for  the  implementation  of   its  programme  of  economic  development  or  economic  transition”.    

 

30  

countries   went   for   more   at   the   Doha   Round   (Public   Citizen,   2009),   with   the   European   representatives   been   among   the   more   aggressive   instigators   (Blustein,   2009).   Nevertheless,   and   away   from   industrialized   economies   pressures,   a   group   of   developing   countries   were   going   beyond   their   commitments92   at   the   GATS-­‐ WTO93.   Signalling   practices   of   this   sort   were   unsurprisingly   common   at   mid-­‐ nineties.   Developed   countries   promptly   realize   this   additional   concession,   becoming  excited  to  institutionalize  it.  Henceforth,  they  began  to  promote  further   compromises   at   new   PTAs.   As   the   usual   leverage   played   at   their   side,   industrialized  countries  introduced  more  stringent  clauses  on  the  bilateral  front  –   later,  under  a  FTA  basis.   Liberalization  at  the  bilateral  and  regional  level:  To  the  infinity  and  beyond   Bilateral   Investment   Agreements   (BITs)   made   their   appearance   on   the   international   scene   at   the   instigation   of   European   investor   countries   seeking   more   protection   for   their   investment   in   emerging   developing   countries,   as   a   way   to   depoliticize   foreign   investment   disputes   in   those   countries.   BITs   fundamental   provisions  include  a  wide  variety  of  principles  and  rules,  counting  those  asserting   the   non-­‐discriminative   treatment   among   foreign   investors   (including   the   Most   Favoured   Nation,   MNF   clause),   entry   and   establishment   conditions,   definition   of   investors   and   investments,   specific   dispute   settlement   provisions,   and   free   transfer   of   payments. But, despite uniformity in broad principles, dissimilarities among treaties were common in the past. The  number  of  PTAs  (basically  BITs,  later  RTAs  &  FTAs)  really  exploded  after  the   Uruguay   Round,   and   mainly   directed   to   increase   foreign   investors   guarantees   along   the   prosecution   of   more   pro-­‐market   policies   (liberalization)   among   Latin   America  and  Eastern  European  countries.  BITs  rose  from  386  agreements  in  1990  

                                                                                                               

92  Commitments  appears  in  schedules,  listing  the  sectors  being  opened,  the  extent  of  market  access   being  given  along  any  limitation  on  national  treatment  introduced  by  the  parties.     93   Undoubtedly,   commitments   to   open   markets   are   the   outcome   of   negotiations   [although   members   have   different   degrees   of   freedom   at   the   negotiation   table].   Comparing   data   on   specific   GATS   commitments  for  financial  services  with  measures  of  actual  policy  in  this  sector  for  123  countries,   Barth,   Caprio   and   Levine   (2006)   conclude   that,   in   practice,   applied   policy   is   much   more   liberal   than   what  committed  to  in  the  GATS.    

 

31  

to   2,676   at   the   end   of   2008,   involving   more   than   180   countries.   Likewise,   over   the   same  period,  IIAs  passed  from  less  than  10  to  259.     The US becomes the main diffuser in this new era, firstly under a bilateral scheme, later through the diffusion of FTAs. Overall, their agreements were basically looking to   improve  market  access  [for  their  transnational  companies]94.  Instructed  with  this   liberalization   mandate,   U.S   negotiators   went   for   more,   at   both   the   bilateral   and   regional  level.  The  signature  of  the  NAFTA  agreement  in  1994  would  become  the   first   step   in   that   direction   (Manger,   2009)95   and,   certainly   very   influential   in   the   region   (Sauvé,   2006).   Under   this   new   scheme,   foreign   investment   liberalization   translated,   among   others,   into   a   broad   definition   of   investment,   increasing   restrictions  on  expropriations  along  other  WTO  plus  requirements.  The  new  model   also   included   stringent   conditions   towards   the   free   transfers   of   funds96,   introducing  an  absolute  standard  with  mostly  any  exceptions  (as  those  related  to   balance   of   payments   crisis).   Likewise,   it   also   followed   a   “negative   list”   approach,   practically   eliminating   all   exceptions97.   In   short,   specific   clauses   in   US   RTAs   and   many   BITs   affected   the   way   that   host   States   could   impact   the   operations   of   the   foreign   investment   established   in   their   territory,   including   more   stringent   conditions   towards   financial   liberalization.   In   this   sense,   the   2004   model   BIT   essentially   forces   partners   to   liberalize   their   capital   accounts,   regardless   of   the   nation’s   institutional   capacity   (Anderson   et.   al.,   2009).   Henceforth,   host   country   policy  room  for  capital  controls  or  safeguards  provisions  are  practically  inexistent.                                                                                                                     94  US  policymakers  opted  as  of  the  1980s  for  dedicated  BITs  targeting  developing  countries,  building  

on   the   success   by   European   investor   countries.   In   the   process,   US   policymakers   become   emboldened   and   included   new   goals   for   their   BITs,   such   as   to   bolster   the   claim   that   the   Hull   rule   remained   customary   international   law   by   establishing   a   network   of   treaties   that   include   this   principle,  and  to  take  advantage  of  the  new  ICSID  general  consent  for  resolving  foreign  investment   disputes  (Mortimore  and  Stanley,  2009).   95   The   framework   introduced   at   NAFTA   Chapter   11   would   become   known   as   “the   1994   model”.   This  

model   text   was   replaced   by   a   modified   version   in   2004.   The   Obama   administration   is   actually   working  in  a  new  version.       96  In  the  vocabulary  of  US  BITs,  funds  could  be  transfer  [by  the  foreign  investor]  freely  and  without   any  delay.     97   By   virtue   of   the   negative   list   approach,   everything   goes   liberalized   unless   the   countries   list   the  

exceptions  to  the  market  access  at  the  time  of  signing  the  FTA.  Two  particular  problems:  a)  at  the   time  of  listing,  the  government  may  not  know  that  a  particular  financial  instrument  actually  present   (and   not   being   listed),   it   becomes   later   dangerous;   and,   b)   even   if   the   government   is   aware   of   all   current  financial  instruments,  because  of  the  list  of  exceptions  is  decided  once  and  for  all  at  the  time   of  signing  the  FTA,  the  government  cannot  list  as  an  exception  financial  instrument  that  come  into   existence  in  the  future  (TWN,  2010).  

 

32  

George   H.   W.   Bush   initiative   “Agenda   for   American   Renewal”   was   certainly   very   ambitious   in   terms   of   financial   deregulation   and   capital   account   liberalization.   Even   after   initiated   the   financial   crisis,   the   US   refused   to   allow   for   any   sort   of   capital  controls  on  the  FTAs  under  negotiations  (Anderson,  2009;  TWN,  2010).  If   Republicans  refused  to  walk  out  on  this  guiding  principle,  with  the  assumption  of   Barak   Obama   at   the   Presidency   other   voices   began   to   be   heard.98   But,   as   the   Korean   experience   will   describe,   the   initial   push   towards   financial   reform   and   institutional   change   ended   to   be   very   weak.   At   the   end,   once   more   Wall   Street’s   interest   prevailed,   and   US   negotiators   maintained   their   former   ideals   of   financial   liberalization  and  bank  deregulation.    

3.2  Argentina  institutional  path  towards  globalization   Foreign  investment  has  played  a  very  important  but  volatile  role  in  the  Argentine   economy  in  the  last  30  years,  strong  during  the  1970s  and  the  1990s,  when  inflows   reached   highs   of   8%   of   GDP   and   virtually   absent   during   the   1980s   debt   crisis.   These   highs   were   associated   with   three   different   types   of   investor:   first,   in   the   1970s,   transnational   banks   that   extended   large   syndicated   loans;   then,   in   the   1990s,  with  financial  intermediaries  who  lent  voluminous  sums  in  bonds  and  TNCS   that   made   very   significant   direct   investments.   In   other   words,   Argentina   was   attractive  to  a  multitude  of  different  foreign  investors  but  in  an  on-­‐again-­‐off-­‐again   manner.   Argentina’s   new   ability   to   attract   foreign   capital   was   based   in   good   part   on   improved   market   prospects   in   the   context   of   the   neo-­‐liberal   reform   program   introduced  by  the  Menem  government  in  the  early  1990s.  The  Convertibility  Law   in   March   1991   was   fundamental   to   stabilizing   the   economy,   based   on   the   introduction  of  a  fixed  one-­‐to-­‐one  dollar-­‐peso  exchange  rate,  after  the  inflationary                                                                                                                   98   Towards   this   end,   the   Obama’s   administration   launched   the   Advisory   Committee   on   International  

Economic   Policy   Submits   Reports   on   Review   of   US   Model   Bilateral   Investment   Treaty,   settled   at   the   Department   of   State,   the   committee   advices   the   US   government   in   international   economic   policy,   including   a   review   on   the   US   model   BITs   (US   Department   of   State,   2009).   In   the   same   direction,   Congressman  Michal  Michaud  (D-­‐Maine),  launched  a  proposal  to  modify  US  BITs  model  in  order  to   preserver   “the   ability   of   each   country   that   is   a   party   to   such   agreement   to   regulate   foreign   investment   in   a   manner   consistent   with   the   needs   and   priorities   of   each   such   country”,   and   that   “allows   each   party   that   is   a   party   to   such   trade   agreement   to   place   prudential   restrictions   on   speculative  capital  to  reduce  global  financial  instability  and  trade  volatility”  (Michaud,  2009  quoted   at  Gallagher  2010,  page  18).  

 

33  

chaos  that  followed  the  debt  crisis  of  the  1980s.  This  extreme  measure  was  costly   in  economic  policy  terms  as  it  effectively  tied  the  hands  of  national  policymakers  in   fiscal  and  monetary  matters;  however,  it  greatly  enhanced  Argentina’s  credibility   with   the   international   investor   community   and   the   Washington-­‐based   international  financial  institutions  (IMF,  World  Bank  and  IDB).   Argentina   signed   over   50   BITs   in   the   1990s   to   provide   increased   protection   to   foreign   investors   in   the   hope   of   attracting   much   greater   quantities   of   foreign   investment.99   More   or   less   simultaneously,   Argentina   moved   ahead   with   an   ambitious   program   of   privatizations   along   a   wide   deregulation   and   liberalization   process.   The   privatizations   soon   became   one   of   the   pillars   of   the   new   economic   program.  From  an  aggregate  point  of  view,  the  sale  of  public  assets  and  the  use  of   the   debt-­‐capitalization   scheme   enabled   Argentina   to   attract   fresh   foreign   investment,  reduce  its  external  debt  and  remove  the  financial  liabilities  generated   by  public  utilities  from  the  public  sphere.  Privatization  was  also  seen  as  focusing   on  a  quest  for  credibility,  tying  the  fate  of  the  privatized  firms  inextricably  to  the   success  of  the  convertibility  plan.   On  23  December  2001  Argentina  shook  the  international  financial  community  by   announcing   a   default   on   its   external   public   debt   of   over   US$   100   billion   –   by   the   time,  a  quarter  of  all  debt  traded  in  the  emerging  bonds  market.  In  January  2002,   the  Argentine  peso  declined  to  one  third  of  its  value  and  the  Government  “pesified”   public   utility   rates   (converting   dollar-­‐denominated   contract   provisions   to   pesos)   provoking  a  large  number  of  IA-­‐ISDS  cases100.  The  Argentine  economy  went  into  a   tailspin   in   good   part   due   to   twin   foreign   investment   crises:   external   public   debt   and  foreign  direct  investment.                                                                                                                   99  Argentina  has  more  BITs  in  force  (54)  than  any  other  LAC  country.  It  has  16  with  industrialized   countries,  such  as  Australia,  Austria,  Belgium  and  Luxembourg,  Canada,  Denmark,  Finland,  France,   Germany,   Italy,   Netherlands,   Portugal,   Spain,   Sweden,   Switzerland,   United   Kingdom,   and   United   States,  as  well  as  38  with  other  countries,  namely,  Algeria,  Armenia,  Bolivia,  Bulgaria,  Chile,  China,   Costa  Rica,  Croatia,  Cuba,  Czech  Republic,  Ecuador,  Egypt,  El  Salvador,  Guatemala,  Hungary,  India,   Indonesia,   Israel,   Jamaica,   Korea,   Lithuania,   Malaysia,   Mexico,   Morocco,   Nicaragua,   Panama,   Peru,   Philippines,   Poland,   Romania,   Russian   Federation,   South   Africa,   Thailand,   Tunisia,   Turkey,   Ukraine,   Venezuela,  and  Viet  Nam,     100  US  President  Roosevelt  introduced  a  similar  policy  in  1933,  when  passed  a  resolution  nullifying   the   gold   clauses   in   both   private   and   public   debt   contracts.   The   validity   of   the   resolution   was   challenged  in  court,  but  the  Supreme  Court  upheld  it.    

 

34  

A  little  over  three  years  later  and  with  no  help  whatsoever  from  the  IMF,  Argentina   shed  its  default  status  when  its  unilateral  offer  was  widely  accepted  (by  over  75%)   by   external   public   debt   bondholders101.   Argentina   achieved   what   no   country   had   achieved   before,   that   is,   the   bondholders   not   only   accepted   a   large   cut   in   principal,   but  also  agreed  to  a  lengthening  of  maturity  and  a  reduction  in  the  interest  rates  to   be  paid.  The  outcome  of  the  swap  far  exceeded  Argentina’s  expectations,  especially   given  that  it  had  worked  out  its  default  unilaterally  without  the  intervention  of  the   international  financial  institutions  or  the  assistance  of  G-­‐7  governments.    A  group   of   unsatisfied   bondholders,   however,   went   to   courts   (US   tribunals).   Tough   a   few   among  them,  mostly  Italian  bondholders,  opted  for  ICSID  facilities.     With   regards   to   the   FDI   crisis,   the   abrupt   end   of   exchange   rate   parity   opened   a   new   front   in   the   dispute   with   foreign   investors,   in   this   case   with   those   who   had   invested   in   the   real   sector,   especially   public   utilities.   Under   the   agreements   signed   in   the   1990s,   foreign   investors   felt   that   they   were   entitled   to   full   compensation   from  the  Government.  Although  most  foreign  investors  in  Argentina  were  affected   by   the   change   in   the   exchange   rate   model,   the   bulk   of   the   complaints   came   from   those   with   some   kind   of   interest   in   public   utilities,   mainly   those   associated   with   the   energy   industry   (gas   and   electric   power).   The   predominance   of   this   type   of   foreign  investment  was  due  not  only  to  the  guarantees  offered  under  BITs  but  also   the  advantages  related  to  national  regulations  (for  example,  rates  set  in  dollars  and   indexed  to  the  United  States  wholesale  price  index).  As  a  result,  national  legislative   provisions,   regulatory   terms   and   the   BIT   network   bound   the   contractual   framework102.     This  mechanism  helped  the  Menem  government  to  demonstrate  its  commitment  to   the   new   international   standards   promoted   by   investor   countries   and   the   Washington   financial   institutions,   but   it   also   became   the   main   base   for   foreign                                                                                                                   101  In  June  2010,  Argentina  reopened  its  debt  exchange,  bringing  the  total  amount  of  restructured  

debt   to   92,6%.   The   high   level   of   acceptance   could   mainly   be   attributed   to   the   share   of   distressed   bonds   held   by   banks   (U$   10   billion   over   a   total   of   U$   20   billion).   Investment   funds   hold   another   U$   4   billion   whereas   the   rest   was   in   hands   of   individuals   and   other   creditors   (iMarketNews.com,   March   23,   2010).     This   second   restructuration   operation,   however,   did   not   include   defaulted   Brady   bonds,  debt  which  Argentina  is  seeking  to  solve  (DowJones.com.  December  6,  2010).     102   Thus,   seeking   to   attract   foreign   investors   and   guarantee   the   success   of   the   reforms,   the   neo-­‐

liberal   Menem   government   ended   up   accepting   a   system   of   “complete”   contracts,   and   thereby   accepting  risks  that  normally  would  be  shouldered  by  the  foreign  investor.  Argentinean  sovereign   bonds  were  also  affected  by  the  problem  of  “complete”  contracts    (Stanley,  2009).        

 

35  

investors’  legal  proceedings.  The  spirit  of  the  restrictions  Argentina  had  imposed   upon  herself  (the  convertibility  scheme  combined  with  the  BITs)  was  to  minimize   the   possibility   of   contract   renegotiation   with   privatized   firms,   since   the   magnitude   of   the   commitments   made   any   alteration,   however   necessary,   too   costly.   Ultimately,   the   crisis   demonstrated   the   intrinsic   “incompleteness”   of   the   contract   scheme  implicit  in  the  regulation  of  the  privatized  firms.  The  collapse  of  economic   policy   and   the   sharp   deterioration   of   the   business   environment   after   successive   administrations   demonstrated   that   the   Menem   government   had   painted   Argentina   into   a   corner   and   the   current   government   it   was   both   unable   and   unwilling   to   abide  by  the  terms  of  the  existing  contracts.  This  produced  a  sharp  reaction  from   foreign   investors,   which   was   manifest   in   a   torrent   (more   than   45)   of   ICSID   lawsuits103   that   raised   the   country’s   contingent   liabilities   to   around   US$   20   billion104.     The   emergency   measures   adopted   by   the   government   affected   the   economic   and   financial   equation   of   foreign   investors.   In   the   case   of   the   regulated   sectors   (with   pesified   rates),   the   higher   the   level   of   indebtedness   in   dollars,   the   larger   was   the   impact   of   these   measures.   Hence,   regardless   of   the   sector,   most   of   the   disputes   brought  after  2002  cited  the  effects  of  the  devaluation  on  contracts  in  general  and   on   the   rate-­‐setting   system   in   particular.   Foreign   investors   maintained   that   the   Government   of   Argentina   had   agreed   to   assume   the   exchange-­‐rate   risk   then   broke   its  promise  in  January  2002.                                                                                                                   103  It  should  be  mentioned  that  five  of  these  were  filed  while  the  convertibility  regime  was  still  in   place.   At   ICSID   were   registered   43   cases,   whereas   3   cases   were   filled   under   the   UNCITRAL   rules.   Awards   have   been   issued   in   12   cases   (3   of   them   denying   jurisdictions   of   the   Claimants,   1   later   suspended);  an  annulment  decision  has  been  issued  in  only  one  case  and  request  for  annulment  are   pending   in   other   six   cases;   one   award   is   being   challenged   before   the   Washington,   DC   courts.   Eighteen   cases   are   still   pending   (including   one   recently   launched,   but   nor   related   to   the   2001   crisis),   and   proceedings   have   been   suspended   or   discontinued   in   18   cases.   The   most   vehement   attacks  came  from  regulated  firms  belonging  to  the  energy  sector  (gas  and  electric  power),  which   initiated   22   lawsuits   (19   before   ICSID   and   3   before   UNCITRAL),   by   virtue   of   the   strong   vertical   and   horizontal  links  presenting  these  industries  (Stanley,  2004).     104   This   total   does   not   include   figures   introduces   by   Italian   bondholders   claims   at   ICISID,   including:   ICSID   case   ARB/07/5   (Giovanna   A.   Beccara   and   Others   v   Argentina   Republic),   case   ARB/07/8   (Giovanni   Alemanni   and   Others   v   Argentina   Republic)   and,   case   ARB/08/9   (Giovanni   Alpi   and   Others   v   Argentina   Republic).   The   fist   one   involved   an   enormous   class-­‐action   style   claim   filed   almost   195.000   Italian   nationals   and   seek   U$   4.4   billion   in   compensation.   The   Alemanni   case   involves   a   small   fraction   of   claimants   asking   for   a   lower   amount   of   reimbursement.   The   third   collective   of   claimants   are   reclaiming   for   a   debt   of   €   6,5   million   plus   U$   560,000   (Luke   Peterson,   “Argentina   Faces  a  Third  Treaty  Claim  by  Holdout  Bondholders:  Experts  differ  as  to  Prospects).    

 

36  

But,   although   most   of   the   cases   cited   more   than   one   cause,   pesification   was   the   primary  motivation  for  the  lawsuits  brought  against  Argentina  (Stanley,  2004).  In   some   cases,   however,   investors´   voracity   was   the   sole   motivation   behind   the   lawsuit  (Stanley,  2009)105.  Whatever  the  reasons  given,  however,  the  filing  of  cases   was   generally   a   strategic   move   towards   positioning   at   the   renegotiation   stance   (utilities)  or  when  asking  for  total  reimbursement  (bondholders).  Hence,  after  the   economic  emergency  legislation  was  passed  and  the  lawsuits  filed,  there  ensued  a   wrangle   between   the   Argentine   Government,   the   foreign   investors   and   the   Washington  financial  institutions  (World  Bank  and  IMF)106.   When   the   Argentine   crisis   broke   out   the   international   system   failed   to   provide   a   solution  to  either  the  losses  of  foreign  investors  caused  by  the  country’s  inability  to   apply  the  rates  stipulated  in  the  original  contracts  or  the  sovereign  default.  Foreign   direct  investors  were  shocked  to  find  that  the  World  Bank  was  unable  to  oblige  the   Argentine   authorities   to   abide   by   the   original   terms   of   utility   contracts.   The   bondholders  found  that  the  IMF  was  unable  to  force  the  Argentine  Government  to   renegotiate  its  debt  under  any  kind  of  pre-­‐existing  scheme  or  provide  assistance  to   bondholders   who   opted   not   to   accept   the   swap   offer   ––“holdouts”––   in   the   hope   of   a   better   deal   from   the   Government   of   Argentina.   For   its   part,   the   Argentine   Government,  in  its  dual  capacity  as  host  country  and  debtor,  was  appalled  by  the   functioning   of   the   international   system,   because   of   the   way   it   explicitly   favoured                                                                                                                   105  

Vulture   funds   ended   with   an   important   portion   of   Argentinean   distressed   sovereign   debt,   obtained  at  deeply  discounted  rates  in  order  to  speculate  in  litigation  against  the  country.  As  most   of  the  bonds  issued  by  Argentina  recognized  New  York  jurisdiction,  claims  were  filled  at  the  US  and   US  District  Judge  Thomas  Griesa  become  in  charge  of  the  claims.         106   The   Argentine   response   began   by   challenging   the   arbitral   tribunal,   questioning   its   transparency,   the  process  by  which  the  arbitration  panel  was  selected  and  the  fact  that  the  foreign  investors  were   allowed   to   engage   in   forum   shopping,   i.e.   select   the   tribunal   most   likely   to   provide   a   favorable   judgment.  By  the  same  token,  Argentina  threatened  not  to  recognize  ICSID’s  jurisdiction,  claiming   that   cases   should   be   heard   in   the   local   courts   first.   Lastly,   in   mounting   a   defense   —that   actually   formulated  in  the  case  of  CMS  Gas  Transmission  Company  and  the  denial  of  jurisdiction  in  others—   the   Government’s   strategy   was   to   deny   that   the   steps   it   had   taken   after   declaring   the   economic   emergency   (i.e.,   pesification   and   rate   freezes)   amounted   to   indirect   expropriation.   Since   all   the   lawsuits   cited   a   single   cause,   the   logic   of   the   economic   emergency   legislation   was   central   to   the   Government’s  strategy.  With  its  proposals  rejected  and  its  arguments  disallowed,  the  Government   shifted   its   stance.   One   of   its   lines   of   approach   was   to   seek   to   have   the   privatized   firms   withdraw   their   suits   as   a   goodwill   gesture   in   the   context   of   contract   renegotiation.   Another,   in   view   of   the   arbitration   tribunal’s   award   in   the   CMS   case,   was   the   Government’s   suggestion   that   it   might   not   acknowledge   any   possible   awards.   Anyway,   at   the   end,   the   government   played   “accommodate”   strategy  (Mortimore  and  Stanley,  2009).      

 

37  

foreign   investors,   the   lack   of   objectivity   of   the   international   financial   institutions   (basically   IMF)   and   attempts   to   condition   the   country’s   economic   policy   to   fulfilment   of   (by   then   impossible)   international   commitments.   As   a   result,   and   in   view   of   the   social   dimension   of   the   crisis,   that   is   between   1999   and   2003   the   proportion   of   Argentines   living   below   the   poverty   line   doubled,   from   27.1   to   54.7%   of   the   population,   the   Government   found   itself   forced   to   choose   between   using   scarce   resources   to   alleviate   the   economic   and   social   suffering   of   the   Argentine   population   caused   by   the   crises   and   allocating   them   to   meet   their   international   obligations   to   foreign   investors.   Action   taken   by   the   Argentina   government   spawned,   in   turn,   “the   greatest   wave   of   claims   by   foreign   investors   against  a  single  host  country  in  recent  history”  (Alvarez  and  Khamsi,  2009).   Ultimately,   the   international   finance   and   investment   community,   which   had   celebrated   Argentina’s   adoption   of   a   risky   neoliberal   policy   framework   failed   to   provide   the   country   with   specific   solutions   to   resolve   the   multiple   crises   it   was   facing.   It   proved   to   be   another   example   of   one   government   limiting   the   policy   options  of  succeeding  governments  to  deal  with  the  crises  provoked  in  large  part   by  the  policies  of  the  former.  Finally,  the  BITs  network  later  became  a  conduit  for   IA-­‐ISDS   demands   by   the   bondholders   that   had   not   accept   the   unilateral   swap   offered  years  earlier.  This  left  the  impression  that  the  IA-­‐ISDS  system  was  warped   to  serve  foreign  investor  interests  at  any  cost.  

3.3  The  KORUS  FTA  and  South  Korea  rupture  with  the  past   South  Korea  was  an  active  contributor  of  the  bilateral  scheme  in  the  past,  signing   its   first   BIT   in   1964   with   Germany.   After   the   signature   of   this   agreement,   Korea   continued   this   trend   and   actually   has   more   than   70   BITs   in   force107.   Agreements                                                                                                                   107   South   Korea   signed   a   total   of   77   BITs,   of   which   68   were   finally   ratified   and   become   legally   binding.  A  total  of  thirty-­‐seven  agreements  were  signed  in  the  nineties,  but  sixteen  in  the  previous   years   and   fifteen   in   the   2000s.   Partners   include:   Albania,   Algeria,   Argentina,   Austria,   Bangladesh,   Belarus,   Belgium   and   Luxembourg,   Bolivia,   Brazil   (not   ratified),   Brunei   Darussalam,   Burkina   Faso   (not   ratified),   Cambodia   Chile   China   Congo   DR,   Costa   Rica   Czech   Republic,   Denmark,   Egypt,   El   Salvador,   Finland,   France,   Germany,   Greece,   Guatemala   Honduras,   Hong   Kong   (China),   Hungary,   India,   Indonesia.   Iran   (not   ratified),   Israel,   Italy,   Jamaica   (not   ratified),   Japan,   Jordan,   Kazakhstan,   Kuwait   (not   ratified),   Lao   PDR,   Latvia,   Lithuania,   Malaysia,   Mauritania   (not   ratified),   Mexico,   Mongolia,   Netherlands   (not   ratified),   Nicaragua,   Nigeria,   Oman,   Pakistan,   Panama,   Paraguay,   Peru,   Philippines,   Poland,   Portugal,   Qatar,   Romania,   Russian   Federation,   Saudi   Arabia   (not   ratified),   Senegal,  Slovakia,  South  Africa,  Spain,  Sri  Lanka,  Sweden,  Switzerland,  Tajikistan,  Thailand,  Trinidad  

 

38  

followed   the   traditional   objective   of   “protecting”   foreign   investments   from   sovereign’s  will.  Despite  the  enthusiasm  on  the  subject,  an  agreement  with  the  US   was  never  achieved.     As   the   country   embraced   a   new   trade   policy   in   the   nineties,   the   government   launched   a   new   market   opening   strategy   institutionalized   by   the   signature   of   PTAs.   In   this   direction,   the   government   commence   negotiations   with   different   partners   around   the   world   which,   as   a   result,   introduced   Korea   at   the   FTAs   scheme,   first   with   Chile108,   later   with   Singapore,   and   the   European   Free   Trade   Association   (EFTA).   Thereafter,   negotiations   were   launched   with   the   Association   of   Southeast   Asian   Nations   (ASEAN)109,   the   European   Union   (EU)110   and   India,   whereas   actually   it   maintain   talks   with   Japan111,   Canada,   Mexico,   Australia,   New   Zealand,  Malaysia  and  MERCOSUR.     The  political  relationship  between  the  US  and  South  Korea  could  be  considered  to   be  special  and  resilient112.  Nevertheless,  trade  relationship  between  both  countries   has   not   been   exempted   from   disagreements.   Foreign   investment,   in   turn,   has                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                       and   Tobago,   Tunisia,   Turkey,   Ukraine,   United   Arab   Emirates,   United   Kingdom,   Tanzania   D.R.   (not   ratified),  Uzbekistan,  and  Vietnam   108  

Chile   becomes   the   first   country   to   have   negotiations   with,   as   Korea   recognized   the   political   experience  in  the  subject  of  his  partner  and,  also,  the  complementarities  between  both  economies.   The  most  difficult  talks  those  dealing  with  agricultural  issues.   109  

The   Framework   Agreement   on   Comprehensive   Economic   Cooperation   (the   FTA   agreement)   becomes   sequentially   negotiated.   The   investment   chapter   was   finally   signed   at   June,   2009,   three   years  later  than  the  agreement  on  goods  and  two  from  the  signature  of  the  one  dealing  with  services   (ASEAN-­‐Korea  FTA  on  Investment  signed.  At  Bilaterals.org,  posted  by  Bernama,  June  2,  2009).     110   To   become   effective   at   July   the   1st   2011,   if   ratified   by   the   European   Parliament   (EU   signs   free-­‐ trade   deal   with   South   Korea,   its   first   with   an   Asian   nation”   Reuters,   Oct   10   2010)   and   introducing   pressure  over  the  US  FTA  approval  (“Obama  gov´t  want  Congress  to  approve  Korea  FTA  beforte  July:   Kirk”  Yonhap,  2011/01/12.       111   Japan   is   Korea’s   second   trading   partner.   Discussions   were   fiercer   as   political   and   historical   demands   added   to   economic   policy   questions   (Cheong,   2002)   as   the   role   of   Japan   in   the   early   twenty-­‐century.   Anti-­‐Japanese   sentiments   are   still   present   in   the   Korean   society,   whose   inhabitants   continues   to   demand   for   a   formal   apology   from   the   former   colonizer   for   past   misdeeds   as   well   as   distortions   in   Japanese   history   textbooks,   territorial   disputes   over   Tokdo   Island,   and   the   issue   of   compensation   for   comfort   women   during   world   war   II.   From   an   economic   perspective,   Korean   policy-­‐makers  were  concerned  about  the  possibility  of  economic  subordination  and  growing  trade   deficit   with   Japan.   Nevertheless,   Ogura   Kazuo,   then   Japanese   Ambassador   to   Korea,   officially   launched   discussions   at   September   1998.     A   month   later,   under   President   Kim   Dae-­‐Jung   visit   to   Japan,  parts  agreed  to  initiated  a  joint-­‐study  on  the  issue   112  The  US  –  South  Korea  military  alliance  have  more  than  fifty  years.  Strategically,  not  only  serves  as   a   buffer   against   the   North   Korean   dictatorship   but   also   to   deter   China´s   increasing   power   in   the   region.    

 

39  

always  been  a  sensitive  topic  in  the  bilateral  economic  relationship  (Cooper,  et.al.;   2010),   reflecting   the   US   interest   at   the   South   Korean   market,   and   the   continues   refusal   of   the   South   Korean   authorities   to   opening   the   economy113.   Differences,   however,  began  to  be  set  aside  at  the  late  1980s  -­‐  early  1990s,  marking  the  passing   of   a   new   era   of   market   friendly   development.   The   completion   of   the   Uruguay   Round   at   1995,   and   Korea   accession   to   the   OECD   in   1996,   strengthened   this   trend.   The  push  towards  financial  liberalization  and  bank  deregulation  continued  its  pace   during  the  nineties,  now  with  the  additional  support  of  the  IMF.     Talks  with  the  US  were  launched  at  Washington,  in  June  2006114.  On  June  30,  2007,   the   two   countries   signed   the   proposed   U.S.   -­‐   South   Korea   Free   Trade   Agreement   (KORUS   FTA).   At   the   moment   the   agreement   is   pending   from   Congressional   approbation  in  South  Korea115  and  the  US116,  although  objections  remains  in  both   sides117.   In   occasion   of   the   G-­‐20   meeting,   both   countries   agreed   to   re-­‐launch   conversations  in  order  to  finally  approve  the  agreement.       KORUS  FTA  structure  resembles  the  structure  of  other  FTAs  previously  signed  by   the   US   administration,   including   the   recently   signed   with   Dominican   Republic   –   Central  American  FTA  (DR-­‐CAFTA).    

                                                                                                                113   Disagreement   reflected,   in   part,   the   Asian   prejudice   to   American   investors   legal   demands.   Although  Asian  countries  were  among  the  most  fervent  adherents  to  BITs,  none  of  their  countries   signed  a  bilateral  agreement  with  the  US  (Stanley,  2008).  However,  South  Korea  and  US  negotiated   an   agreement   but   failed   over   US   opposition   to   South   Korea’s   so-­‐called   screen   quota   on   domestic   films  and  the  latter’s  resistance  to  lifting  or  reducing  it  (Cooper,  2010).           114   In   the   late   80s   the   US   government   become   firstly   interested   at   Korean   openness.   Talks   among  

partners   began   over   Korea’s   large   merchandise   trade   surplus   with   the   US   favoured   by   an   undervalued  won  –  as  for  the  US  negotiations  (Amsden,  2001;  page  329).     115   The   KORUS   would,   soon   or   later,   be   approved   at   South   Korea,   as   the   ruling   party   controls   the  

Unicameral  National  Assembly.  Furthermore,  the  Assembly’s  Foreign  Affairs,  Trade  and  Unification   Committee  have  already  approved  the  agreement  (Cooper;  et.al.,  2010).     116   Negotiations   in   the   US   Congress   were   conducted   under   the   Trade   Promotion   Authority   (TPA).   In   order   the   agreement   to   enter   into   force,   the   Congress   should   approve   implementation   legislation.   It   is  expected  that  President  Barack  Obama  will  submit  the  agreement  to  Congress  at  January  2011.   117   During   the   last   Presidential   meeting   on   November   11,   2010,   South   Korea’s   President,  Lee   Myung-­‐ bak   and   US   President   Barack   Obama   announced   that   had   not   resolved   the   outstanding   issues,   as:   agriculture  (including  beef,  rice,  oranges,  and  sanitary  and  phytosanitary  provisions);  autos;  textiles   and   apparel;   and   other   manufactured   goods   (capital   goods   machinery   and   equipment;   electronic   products  and  components;  and,  steel)        

 

40  

The   general   principles   settled   down   in   the   agreement   include   a   far-­‐reaching   definition  of  investment118,  the  principle  of  national  treatment,  the  most-­‐favoured-­‐ nation   treatment,   the   minimum   standard   of   treatment.   Likewise,   KORUS   FTA   set   limits   on   government   expropriation   of   covered   investments.   It   also   require   each   partner   to   allow   for   the   free   transfer   of   financial   capital   pertaining   to   covered   investment  both  into  and  out  of  the  country,  although  it  allows  some  exceptions119.   Finally,   and   similarly   to   most   modern   agreements,   KORUS   FTA   establish   procedures   for   the   settlement   of   investor-­‐state   disputes   involving   investment   covered  under  the  agreement.     The   two   countries   committed   to   provide   national   treatment   and   most-­‐favoured-­‐ nation  treatment  to  the  services  imports  from  each  other;  promoted  transparency   in   the   development   and   implementations   of   regulations   in   services   providing   timely   notice   of   decisions   on   government   permission   to   sell   services;   prohibit   limits  on  market  access;  prohibit  foreign  direct  investment  requirements,  such  as   export  and  local  content  requirement  and  employment  mandates120;  and,  prohibit   restrictions  on  the  type  of  business  entity  through  which  a  service  provider  could   provide   a   service121.   It   allows   U.S.   companies   to   supply   financial   services   on   a   cross-­‐border   basis,   including   management   services   for   investment   funds   and   international   transit   insurances.   Likewise,   the   two   countries   agreed   to   the   “negative   list”   approach   in   making   commitments   in   services   –   a   really   valuable   principle  obtained  by  US  negotiators.                                                                                                                       118   Investment   includes:   investment   agreements   between   a   government   and   a   foreign   firm   with  

respect   to   natural   resources,   certain   procurement   construction   activities   and   more;   investment   authorizations;  enterprises;  shares,  stock,  and  other  forms  of  equity  participation  in  an  enterprise;   bonds,   debentures,   other   debt   instruments,   and   loans;   futures,   options,   and   other   derivatives;   turnkey,   construction,   management;   production,   concession,   revenue-­‐sharing,   and   other   similar   contracts;  intellectual  property  rights;  licenses,  authorizations,  permits,  and  similar  rights  conferred   pursuant  to  domestic  law;  and  other  tangible  and  intangible,  movable  or  immovable  property,  and   related  property  rights,  such  as  leases,  mortgages,  liens,  and  pledges.     119  Originally  Korean  negotiators  wanted  safeguards  applicable  in  case  of  foreign  exchange  crisis,  a  

petition   refused   by   the   US.   At   the   end,   parts   agreed   to   introduce   safeguard   at   the   cost   of   maintaining  financial  liberalization  (Ahn,  2008).  

120   Under   chapter   13,   neither   party   could   require   financial   institutions   of   the   other   party   to   hire   individuals  of  a  particular  nationality  as  senior  managers  or  other  essential  personnel,  nor  could  a   party  require  more  than  a  minority  of  the  board  of  directors  to  be  nationals  or  residents  of  the  other   party  (USITC,  2010,  at  page  4-­‐9)   121  In  particular,  each  party  would  be  required  to  permit  a  financial  institution  of  the  other  party  to   provide   new   financial   services   on   the   same   basis   that   it   permits   its   own   domestic   institutions   to   provide  (USITC,  2010,  at  page  4-­‐9).    

 

41  

According   to   the   agreement,   South   Korea   committed   to   reduce   barriers   to   trade   and   investment   in   its   services   sector,   including   the   financial.   Furthermore,   it   guarantees  the  right  to  full  American  ownership  of  a  financial  institution  in  Korea.   It   might   also   be   the   case   that   Korean   prudential   regulations   be   deemed   illegal   under  the  new  treaty  (Gallagher,  2010b).   In   addition,   the   agreement   commits   partners   to   refrain   from   limiting   the   size   of   financial   institutions   (PublicWatch,   2010).   Likewise,   the   commitments   are   ratcheted,   meaning   that   when   new   services   emerge   in   one   of   the   economies,   the   FTA   automatically   covers   those   services   –   unless   identified   as   an   exception   (Cooper;   et.al,   2010).   Finally,   in   relation   to   the   capital   control   issue,   the   KORUS   FTA   financial   chapter   might   be   read   as   forbidding   any   limit   to   the   transfer   of   capital  (PublicWatch,  2010).     The  agreement  has,  without  doubt,  important  diplomatic  and  security  implications   (Schott,  2007;  Cooper,  et.al.,  2010).  From  an  economic  perspective,  the  agreement   could   reinforce   trade   and   investment   flows   between   partners122.   For   the   US   the   agreement   entails   a   diplomatic   victory,   which   helps   to   restricts   the   increasing   Chinese   influence   in   Asia   (Ahn,   2008;   Cooper,   et.al.,   2010).   Looking   at   the   financial   and   other   services   chapters123,   it   become   evident   that   the   US   obtained   a   great   deal   (Cooper,   et.al.;   2010)124,   certainly,   a   “model   agreement   in   financial   services”   (www.KOREAUSPartnerhip.org125),   “no   better,   more   sophisticated   trade   arrangement  for  financial  firms”    (Toppeta,  2010)126.  In  particular,  under  the  terms   of  the  FTA  Korea’s  remaining  nontariff  impediments  to  banking  services  stands  at                                                                                                                   122  

Korea   is   the   United   States   seventh-­‐largest   trading   partner   based   on   total   trade.   The   US   merchandises  trade  balance  with  Korea  moved  from  a  $  2,9  billion  surplus  in  1996  to  a  $  13,9  billion   deficit   in   2006.   In   2005,   US   services   exports   to   Korea   were   approximately   $   10,3   billion,   and   US   services  imports  from  Korea  were  $  6,3  billion.  On  the  other  hand,  the  US  holds  the  largest  single-­‐ country  share  of  FDI  stock  in  Korea,  with  30%  (USITC,  2010).     123  Trade  in  services  cut  across  several  chapters  of  the  KORUS  FTA:  Chapter  12  (cross-­‐border  trade   in   services);   Chapter   13   (financial   services);   and   Chapter   15   (Telecommunications);   Chapter   11   (foreign  investment);  among  others.     124  See,  for  example,  a  collection  of  statements  of  support  for  the  US-­‐Korea  Trade  Agreement  at  the   US  White  House  web  page.     125  The  Korea-­‐US  Trade  Partnership  declared  it  as  “a  groundbreaking  achievement,  providing  more  

extensive  provisions  related  to  financial  services  than  ever  before  included  in  a  U.S.  FTA”.     126  Remarks  by  William  J.  Toppeta,  President  –  International  MetLife.  April  6.      

 

42  

29%,  well  below  the  actual  76%  accepted  by  Korea  at  GATS127 .  Citigroup´s  Laure   Lane   and   corporate   co-­‐chair   of   the   US-­‐Korea   FTA   Business   Coalition,   made   a   similar   statement,   qualifying   it   as   “the   best   financial   chapter   negotiated   in   a   free   trade   agreement   to   date”128.   KORUS   FTA   obtained   the   support   of   both,   big   trade   unions  

and  

business  

associations  

(US  

government,  

http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-­‐press-­‐office/2010/12/03/statements-­‐support-­‐ us-­‐korea-­‐trade-­‐agreement).   As   a   result,   the   US   service   sector   is   particularly   exultant   with   KORUS   FTA   approval,   as   the   agreement   includes   liberalization   measures  “in  excess  of  the  current  General  Agreement  on  Trade  in  Services  (GATS)   regime”   (USITC,   2010).129   Surprisingly   enough,   instead   to   focus   on   the   increased   access   to   the   US   market,   South   Korean   negotiators   emphasized   “the   medium   and   long-­‐term   gains   that   would   stem   from   increased   allocative   efficiency   of   the   South   Korean  economy,  particularly  in  the  services  industries”.    

                                                                                                               

127  Non-­‐tariff  impediments  are  condensed  in  a  measure:  the  tariff  equivalent    (TE),  which  measures   the  percentage  increase  in  prices  due  to  trade  impediments  relative  to  the  price  that  would  exist  in   the  absence  of  trade  restrictions.   128  She  participates  as  corporate  co-­‐chair  of  the  US-­‐Korea  FTA  Business  Coalition.     129   However,   the   agreements   have   also   its   detractors   in   the   US,   among   them   NGO   Public   Citizen’s  

Trade  Watch  (www.tradewatch.org).  Public  Citizen’s  doubts  relates  to  the  increasing  rights  granted   to  South  Korean  investors  by  the  treaty,  which  could  end  challenging  US  judiciary  autonomy.  

 

43  

 

4.  Conclusions   4.1  A  hard  learning  process:  Lesson  1  –  Argentina     The   vagaries   of   the   relationship   between   foreign   investors   and   host   countries   sometimes  favoured  the  former,  and  sometimes  benefited  the  latter.  In  the  1990s,   however,   the   balance   tipped   excessively   towards   foreign   investors,   as   they   had   managed  to  enhance  the  guarantees  and  legal  certainty  that  developing  countries   and   transition   economies   provided,   by   introducing   into   their   contracts   with   debtors   a   series   of   clauses   waiving   sovereign   immunity   in   the   case   of   default   (as   the   transnational   banks   had   done   in   the   1970s   under   the   syndicated   loan   system).   Foreign  investor’s  guarantees  and  advantages  were  then  further  expanded  as  the   bilateral   scheme   become   more   widespread   and   a   dispute   settlement   mechanism   was  introduced  enabling  them  to  sue  the  host  country  directly.  Argentina  became   the  first  sovereign  nation  to  experience  the  muscle  of  this  new  scheme.     When   the   Argentine   crisis   broke   out,   however,   the   international   system   failed   to   provide   a   solution   to   either   the   sovereign   default   or   the   losses   of   foreign   investors   caused   by   the   country’s   refusal   to   apply   the   rates   stipulated   in   the   original   contract.  The  bondholders  were  horrified  to  find  that  the  IMF  was  unable  to  force   the   Argentine   Government   to   renegotiate   its   debt   under   any   kind   of   pre-­‐existing   scheme  or  provide  assistance  to  bondholders  who  opt  not  to  accept  the  swap  offer   –holdouts-­‐  in  the  hope  of  a  better  proposal  from  the  Government  of  Argentina.  For   its  part,  the  Argentine  Government,  in  its  dual  capacity  as  debtor  and  host  country,   was   also   appalled   by   the   functioning   of   the   international   system,   because   of   the   way   it   explicitly   favoured   foreign   investors,   the   lack   of   objectivity   of   the   international   financial   institutions   (basically   IMF)   and   attempts   to   condition   the   country’s  economic  policy  to  fulfilment  of  international  commitments.  As  a  result,   and   in   view   of   the   social   dimension   of   the   crisis,   the   Government   found   itself   forced   to   choose   between   using   resources   to   alleviate   the   social   suffering   caused   by   the   crisis   and   allocating   them   to   its   international   obligations   to   foreign   investors.   As   push   comes   to   shove,   the   government   opted   not   to   renegotiate  

 

44  

contracts   and   massively   defaulted   on   their   external   obligations   at   the   price   of   being  forced  to  a  financial  asylum  since  then130.     The   Argentinean   case   results   interesting,   furthermore,   because   it   exemplifies   the   malfunctioning   of   capital   controls.   During   the   2001-­‐02   crisis   investors   profited   from  the  legal  loopholes  at  stock  market  in  order  to  legally  flight  capitals  abroad.   In   particular,   investors   used   their   bank   deposits   either   to   purchase   Argentine   stocks  listed  at  the  NYSE  [an  equity  termed  American  Depository  Receipts  (ADRs)]   or,   by   a   lesser   extent,   throughout   the   purchasing   of   shares   of   non-­‐Argentinean   firms   at   the   local   stock   market   [the   so   called,   CEDEARs].   Capital   outflows   resurged   under  the  Kirchner  administration,  as  investors  lost  confidence  on  the  government   economic   macroeconomic   programme   following   the   crisis   with   the   rural   constituency.   Uncertainty   rose   thereafter   as   political   turmoil   and   social   tension   mounted,  initiating  a  new  phase  of  capital  flights.  Outflows  were  also  responding   to   external   factors,   as   the   collapse   of   Lehman   Brothers   at   September   2008   and   the   collapse   at   international   financial   markets   that   followed.   The   first   case   demonstrates   the   relevance   of   properly   closing   legal   leaks   as   investors   quickly   profited   from   all   legal   loopholes   to   flow   out   their   capital   from   the   country.   The   second  highlights  the  ineffectiveness  of  capital  controls  if  macroeconomic  policies   are  not  properly  functioning.     The   Argentinean   experience   also   raises   serious   doubts   on   the   Basle   rules   effectiveness,   particularly   in   the   measuring   of   systematic   risk   in   emerging   economies.   Prudential   regulation   overestimate   private   agents   capacity   to   take   decisions   properly,   under   a   context   where   price   signals   became   highly   distorted   and   the   rules   of   the   game   were   ultimately   unstable   (Damill,   et.   al.,   2010).     In   other   words,   the   monetary   trilemma   cannot   be   eluded   even   if   the   banking   industry   is   being  “properly”  regulated.       Finally,   from   an   institutional   perspective,   and   considering   the   recent   financial   crisis,   might   be   constructive   to   reconsider   the   Argentina   experience   at   ICSID.   At                                                                                                                   130   Completely   aisled   from   international   markets,   the   government   becomes   forced   to   fulfil   their   foreign   exchange   necessities   by   means   of   three   sources:   current   account   surplus,   multilateral   lending   and   by   the   selling   of   Central   Bank’s   reserves.   Increasing   commodities   prices,   including   soybean  and  other  crops,  boosted  government  fiscal  resources  (as  the  exports  of  agricultural  goods   are  being  taxed).    

 

45  

the   beginning   of   the   new   millennium,   and   following   the   collapse   of   their   economy,   social   disruption   and   a   massive   political   turmoil,   foreign   investors   rushed   to   international   arbitrational   courts   in   order   to   maintain   their   privileges.   As   an   example,   take   the   CMS   case   against   the   country,   on   which   the   Argentinean   government   sustained   it   exemption   from   any   liability   for   breaching   the   US-­‐ Argentina   BIT   on   the   grounds   that   a   state   of   necessity   (the   financial,   economic,   social   and   political   crises   in   the   context   of   which   the   emergency   measures   were   taken)131,  an  argument  based  on  customary  international  law  and  Article  XI  of  the   US-­‐Argentina   BIT.   The   tribunal   did   not   accept   Argentina’s   necessity   defense,   and   awarded   CMS   US$   133   million   in   compensation132.   The   ruling   was   later   partially   annulled,   but   the   decision   on   the   state   of   necessity   was   upheld133.   After   considering   the   Argentinean   experience,   some   legal   scholars   were   wondering   why   foreign  investors  claims  against  the  US  have  not  yet  materialized  (Peterson,  2009;   Reed,   2010).   In   view   of   the   set   of   measures   introduced   since   2008134   and   after   carefully   reading   most   prominent   economist,   an   arbitrator   might   seriously   tempted   to   consider   whether   US   policies   responded   to   a   “grave   and   imminent   peril”;  and  whether  the  measures  were  “the  only  steps  available”  to  safeguard  its   interest.   Furthermore,   it   could   affirm   those   government   policies   and   their   shortcomings  significantly  contributed  to  the  crisis.                                                                                                                    

131   The   CMS   and   LG&E   cases,   both   involving   United   States   investors   in   the   Argentine   natural   gas   distribution  market,  and  both  concerning  emergency  measures  taken  by  the  Argentine  government   over   the   period   of   1999   to   2002,   resulted   in   conflicting   conclusions   regarding   the   “necessity   defence”.  The  discussion  on  the  necessity  defence  brings  to  the  surface  the  tension  between  national   policy   space   and   foreign   investment   protection,   and   the   contradictory   awards   in   the   two   cases   reveal  the  problem  of  incoherence  in  arbitral  decisions  under  the  ICSID  rules   132  Although  the  tribunal  understood  that  neither  the  essential  interests  of  the  United  States  nor  of   the   international   community   had   been   seriously   impaired   by   the   measures   taken   by   Argentina,   it   questioned   whether   “an   essential   interest”   of   the   State   (of   Argentina)   was   at   stake,   whether   there   was   a   “grave   and   imminent   peril”;   and   whether   the   measures   taken   by   Argentina   were   “the   only   steps  available”  to  safeguard  its  interest.  It  also  affirmed  that  Argentina’s  “government  policies  and   their  shortcomings  significantly  contributed  to  the  crisis”.  Since  the  conditions  for  acceptance  of  a   necessity  defence  must  be  cumulatively  satisfied,  the  Tribunal  ruled  that  the  necessity  defence  was   not  applicable  under  customary  international  law.     133  In  a  similar  case,  paradoxically,  the  ICSID  tribunal  recognized  the  potential  severity  of  economic   crises,   accepting   the   necessity   defence   for   a   specific   period   (from   December   21,   2001   to   April   26,   2003),   “during   which   it   was   necessary   to   enact   measures   to   maintain   public   order   and   protect   its   essential  security  interest”.  In  other  words,  the  “state  of  necessity”  was  recognized.     134   The   US   government   initiated   a   series   of   extensive   market   interventions   after   2008,   starting   with   Fannie  Mae  and  Freddie  Mac  bailed  out,  to  continue  with  large  sums  of  capital  injections  to  several   car  manufacturers  and  US  banks.  Foreign  investors  might  also  try  to  challenge  the  local  –  purchasing   requirement  introduced  by  the  US  government.    

 

46  

A  hard  learning  process:  Lesson  2  –  South  Korea   Among  divergences  presented  by  these  two  countries,  South  Korea  differentiated   from  Argentina  at  having  desisted  to  participate  in  any  RTAs  with  the  US.  This,  in   turn,  might  have  prevented  Korea  to  be  legally  challenge  at  international  courts  at   the   aftermath   of   the   previous   crises.   However,   this   could   easily   pass   away   if   the   KORUS   FTA   is   finally   approved   –   increasing   the   fiscal   costs   of   an   eventual   new   crisis.  At  the  midst  of  the  financial  storm,  and  after  re-­‐introducing  capital  controls   in   order   to   stop   economic   agents   to   destabilize   the   national   economy,   but   the   government   might   be   accepting   an   agreement   that   penalize   this   sort   of   policies.     Likewise,   considering   the   negative   list   approach   followed   at   KORUS,   the   Korean   government  might  found  surprised  by  the  explosive  potential  of  existing  financial   instruments  or  the  perils  associated  with  appearance  of  new  ones.       On  relation  to  the  monetary  trilemma  and  the  Korean  response,  authorities  in  the   nineties   opted   began   to   move   away   from   capital   controls   introducing,   instead   sterilization   measures   along   encouraging   capital   outflows.   But,   their   efficacies   become   contested   when   financial   volatility   was   back.   Volatility,   in   turn,   becomes   more   pronounced   at   the   latest   crisis   because,   in   contrast   to   the   nineties,   the   Korean   economy   was   now   more   open   to   international   markets.   As   observed   in   Argentina   when   contrasting   the   nineties   against   the   eighties,   the   older   “buffers”   that   prevented   financial   leaking   during   the   past   crisis   were   lately   absent.   Furthermore,   in   contrast   to   the   1997   crisis,   under   the   latest   portfolio   (mainly   equity)   investment   and   borrowings   outperformed   FDI   inflows.   The   banking   industry,   on   the   other   hand,   advanced   in   the   compliment   of   international   standards  and,  without  doubt,  the  Korean  financial  sector  become  more  open  and   internationalized  than  in  the  previous  crisis.  Nevertheless,  the  economy  increased   their  vulnerabilities  to  sudden  large-­‐scale  withdrawals  of  foreign  capital.  In  other   words,   as   the   capital   account   happens   to   be   more   open   and   the   bank   industry   more  deregulated,  chances  for  increasing  volatility  are  becoming  more  important,   showing  how  relevant  become  to  better  manage  financial  opening  or  to  advance  in   the  controlling  of  capital  inflows  (Kim,  undated).  In  the  same  direction,  Lee,  Kim,   Kim   and   Song   (2010)   are   suggesting   an   “intermediate”   macro-­‐financial   system,   with   partial   capital   controls,   a   flexible   exchange   rate   system,   and   relative    

47  

independence   in   monetary   policymaking.   Their   so-­‐called   structuralist   policy   also   considers   the   relevance   of   sound   regulation   and   supervision,   including   a   correct   assessment  of  spreads  movements  (Lee,  et.al.,  2010)135.      

A  hard  learning  process:  Lesson  3  –  Crisis,  what  crisis?   Financial   liberalization   did   not   bring   the   benefits   originally   predicted;   instead   it   increased   macroeconomic   volatility   and   market   turmoil.   Among   others,   and   constructed   after   the   experience   of   Argentina   and   the   Korea   Republic,   this   paper   found   two   points   important   to   discuss   followed   by   a   caveat   on   institutions   and   international  financial  architecture.   On   the   one   hand,   the   present   situation   show   how   dysfunctional   could   capital   inflows   be   for   the   hosting   economy   if   unregulated.   But,   capital   management   techniques   are   unquestionably   back   into   the   discussion   and   certainly   trendy   between   academic   and   policy   -­‐   makers.   Suddenly,   policy   makers   along   academic   researchers   in   the   north   become   aware   of   the   problem   imposed   by   financial   deregulation   and   capital   market   liberalization.   However,   emerging   markets   joy   continues   to   be   legally   contested   by   virtue   of   the   WTO   commitments   plus   RTAs   specific  clauses  originally  signed.     Whereas   regulation   for   managing   systematic   risk   is   commonly   accepted,   this   has   not  been  the  case  for  government  involvement  in  exchange  risks  management.  The   currency-­‐mismatching   problem,   appearing   firstly   in   the   seventies,   has   certainly   been   more   relevant   among   developing   countries   and   emerging   economies136.   Unfortunately,  this  problem  is  not  part  of  the  agenda.  Partly  because  this  issue  is   relevant   only   to   EM   economies   and   they   have   little   influence   in   setting   up   a   new   financial  architecture.  The  cases  being  analysed  showed  that  cross-­‐border  finance   has   been   left   almost   entirely   out   of   the   agenda.   In   particular,   it   has   not   required                                                                                                                  

135   The   authors   note   that   currency   crisis   pivoted   around   the   government’s   withdraw   from   regulating   the   real   side   of   economy,   the   financial   sector,   and   especially   the   international   capital   market,  the  so-­‐called  “Frenkel-­‐Neftci”  cycle  has  began.     136   All   commercial   banks   have   maturity   mismatch   problem   as   they   borrow   short-­‐term   money   and   lend  the  funds  to  individuals  and  companies  in  a  long  term.  The  maturity  mismatch  occurs  directly   due   to   the   time   structure   of   interest   rates,   but   also   due   to   the   structural   inconsistency   of   the   financial  system.    

 

48  

any   regulation   on   the   subject   as   currency   mismatching   was   no   part   of   the   global   finance   (Lee   et.al.,   2010;   Ocampo,   2010).   Similarly,   Basel   II   dominated   financial   regulation   and   bank   supervision,   but   inducing   self-­‐regulation   and   avoiding   to   tangle  the  problem  posed  by  the  presence  of  uncertainty.  Henceforth,  liquidity  risk   was   absent   in   the   discussion   (Lee   et.al.,   2010),   being   the   Financial   Stability   Fund   (FSF,  2008)  the  only  entity  beginning  to  work  on  the  problem.   The   international   financial   crisis   has,   on   the   other   hand,   also   showed   how   inappropriate  the  current  international  monetary  and  financial  architecture  is  for   managing   today’s   global   economy.   To   prevent   future   crisis,   sound   regulation   and   supervision  are  necessary.  Capital  controls  are  part  of  the  toolkit,  but  certainly  nor   the   simply   response   for   the   monetary   trilemma   neither   a   panacea   at   preventing   sudden   stops.   The   calls   for   and   steps   to   taken   to   reform   such   architecture   are,   therefore,   welcome.   Similar   calls   for   reform   were,   however,   as   well   made   after   the   sequence   of   Asian,   Russian   and   Latin   American   crises,   but   they   led   at   best,   to   marginal  reforms  in  the  international  architecture  (Wade,  2009).  In  contrast,  both   IFIs   evaluation   programmes   and   institutional   reforms   induced   by   the   Basle   Agreement,   continued   to   constrain   developing   countries   policy   space   (Stalling,   2006).  The  fact  that  this  time  industrial  economies  have  been  at  the  centre  of  the   storm   brings   hope   to   firmer   action   (Ocampo,   2010),   along   the   expectation   for   a   profound   change   at   the   international   financial   architecture.   Certainly,   only   when   the   crisis   arrived   to   northern,   developed,   countries   the   IFIs   message   became   to   change137.     But,  despite  IMF  new  mood,  initiatives  at  Basel,  and  new  US  financial  regulations,   private   actors   and   US   negotiators   continue   to   push   emerging   and   developing   countries   to   liberalize   their   financial   services.   Correspondingly,   a   real   banking   reform   has   been   postponed   once   more.   Whether   this   reflects   incapacity   to   domesticate  powerful  financial  lobbies  or  the  fact  that  those  regulating  them  have   been  captured  (Stiglitz,  2010)  is  beyond  the  scope  of  this  paper.  On  the  contrary,   despite  former  initiatives  launched  towards  an  institutional  reshaping,  the  US  BIT   model  maintains  its  pressure  towards  increasing  financial  liberalization  and  bank                                                                                                                  

137  Certainly  some  professionals  working  at  the  IMF  were  reluctant  to  endorse  the  official  position   after  the  Asian  crisis.    

 

49  

deregulation.  However,  this  might  not  be  neither  surprising  not  at  all  inconvenient   [for   the   US]138.   But,   also,   the   above   push   might   also   be   revelling   Wall   Street   weight   at  the  decision-­‐making  process  at  Washington  and  the  solidity  of  the  services  led   growth   model   –   despite   sceptics.   The   institutional   continuity   might   be   showing   that   concerns   over   the   global   economic   and   financial   markets   were   imprecise   (crisis,  what  crisis?),  and  the  pragmatism  US  policy.  

                                                                                                                138  From  a  strategic  perspective,  this  vision  might  not  be  surprising  if  considering  the  relevance  of   the  services  industry  for  the  US  economy.  On  the  one  hand,  in  quantitative  terms,  it  represents  more   than  ¾  of  the  country  gross  domestic  product,  employing  4  out  from  5  of  their  labour  force.  On  the   other   hand,   American   service   companies   qualify   among   the   most   competitive   and   efficient   in   the   market  (USITC,  2010).  

 

50  

 

6.  References   Ahn,   Ch-­‐y   (2008).   Satisfaction   in   your   toil:   the   long   road   to   the   Korea-­‐U.S.   Free   Trade  Deal.  Global  Asia,  Vol.  2  Nº  1.   Anderson,   S.   (2009).   Investment   Protection   in   U.S.   Trade   and   Investment   Agreements.   Testimony   to   the   U.S.   House   Ways   and   Means   Committee,   subcommittee  on  Trade.     Bhagwati,   J.   (1998).   The   Capital   Myth:   The   Difference   between   Trade   in   Widgets   and  Dollars.  Foreign  Affairs;  May/Jun  77:3.   Blustein,  P.  (2005).  And  the  money  kept  rolling  in  (and  out):  Wall  Street,  the  IMF   and  the  Bakrupting  of  Argentina.  PublicAffairs.  New  York.     -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐  (2009).  Misadventures  of  the  Most  Favored  Nations.  PublicAffairs.  New   York.     BOK   (2009).   Changes   in   Foreign   Investors´   Behaviour   in   Korean   Stock   Market   in   Response   to   Changes   in   the   International   Investment   Environment.   Bank   of   Korea,   2009-­‐03-­‐31  (http://www.bok.or.kr/eng/index.jsp).       Bradford,   C.   and   J.   Linn   (2010).   It´s   time   to   drop   the   G8.   Paul   Blainstein   et.   al.   “Recovery   or   Relapse:   The   Role   of   the   G20   in   the   Global   Economy”.   Global   Economy  and  Development  at  Brookings.       Buiter,   W.   (2009).   The   return   of   capital   controls.   VOX   Research-­‐based   policy   analysis  and  commentary  from  leading  economists,  20  February.     Burdisso,   T.   and   L.   D´Amato   (1999).   Prudential   regulations,   restructuring   and   competition:  the  case  of  the  Argentine  Banking  Industry.  Central  Bank  of  Argentina   (BCRA),  Working  Paper  Nº  10.     Calvo,   G.   (2010).   Capital   controls   cannot   stabilise   emerging   economies.   FT.com/beyondbrics.    

 

51  

Cheong,   I.   (2002).   Korea´s   FTA   Policy:   Focusing   on   Bilateral   FTAs   with   Chile   and   Japan.   Korea   Institute   for   International   Economy   Policy   –   KIEP   Discussion   Paper   02-­‐02.   Chwieroth,   J.   M.   (2005).   U.S.   Policy,   IMF   Financing   Arrangements,   and   the   Coercive   Diffusion   of   Capital   Account   Liberalization   to   Emerging   Markets.   European   University  Institute  –  EUI  Working  Papers  RSCAS  Nº  2005/06.   -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐,   A.   Hicks   and   D.   Pinheiro   (2009).   The   New   Institutionalism   and   Economic   Globalization:   The   Case   of   Capital   Account   Liberalization   in   Latin   America.  

Mimeo  

(http://personal.lse.ac.uk/chwierot/Images/NewInstitutionalism.pdf).     Cooper,  W.;  M.  Manyin;  R.  Jurenas  and  M.  Platzer  (2010).  The  Proposed  U.S.-­‐South   Korea   Free   Trade   Agreement   (KORUS   FTA):   Provisions   and   Implications.   Congressional  Research  Service  (CRS),  Report  for  Congress.   DeLong,   B.   (2004).   Should   we   still   support   untrammelled   International   capital   mobility?  Or  ar  capital  controls  less  evil  than  we  once  believed?  The  Economists´   Voice,  Volume  1,  Issue  1     Diaz-­‐Alejandro,   C.   (1985).   Good-­‐Bye   financial   repression,   hello   financial   crash.   Journal  of  Development  Economics,  19  (1-­‐2):  1.24.   Dieter,  H.  (2010).  Imbalances  do  matter,  but  how  to  reduce  them?  Paper  prepared   for  the  Conference  on  International  Cooperation  in  Times  of  Global  Crisis  –  Views   from  G20  Countries.  New  Delhi,  16-­‐17  September.   Dymski,   G.   (2010).   The   Global   Crisis   and   the   Governance   of   Power   in   Finance.   In   Philip   Arestis,   Rogerio   Sobreira   and   Jose   Luis   Oreiro   The   2008   Financial   Crisis,   Financial  Regulation,  and  Global  Impact.  Palgrave.     Eichengreen,  B.  (1998).  Capital  Controls:  Capital  Idea  or  Capital  Folly?  Mimeo   -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   (2002).   Capital   Account   Liberalization   and   Growth:   Was   Mr.   Mahathir  Right?  Mimeo.    

 

52  

-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   (2005).   Capital   Account   Liberalization   and   the   Fund.   Paper   prepared   for   the   High   Level   Seminar   on   Capital   Account   Liberalization   and   the   IMF,  held  at  the  Swiss  Ministry  of  Finance.  12  December,  Bern  -­‐  Switzerland.     -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   (2007).   The   Cautious   Case   for   Capital   Flows.   Paper   prepared   for   Rating  Agency  Malaysia’s  conference  on  “Free  Capital  Mobility:  What’s  in  store  for   Asia”,  held  in  Singapore  on  1  August.     -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐  (2008).  Global  Imbalances  and  the  Lessons  of  Bretton  Woods.  The   Cairoli  Lectures,  The  MIT  Press.     -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   (2010).   Managing   Openness:   Lessons   from   the   Crisis   for   Emerging   Markets.  BOK  Discussion  Paper   Epstein,   G.   (2009).   Should   Financial   Flows   be   Regulated?   Yes.   G24   Discussion   Paper,  Washington  D.C.   -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐,   I.   Grabel   and   K.   S.   Jomo   (2008).   Capital   Management   Techniques   in   Developing  Countries:  Managing  Capital  Flows  in  Malaysia,  India  and  China.  In  José   Antonio   Ocampo   and   Joseph   E.   Stiglitz   (eds)   Capital   Market   Liberalization   and   Development.  The  Initiative  for  Policy  Dialogue  Series  –  Oxford  Press.     Financial  Times  (2010).  S  Korea  plans  capital  controls.  October  19   Gallagher,   K.   (2010a).   Policy   Space   to   Prevent   and   Mitigate   Financial   Crisis   in   Trade  and  Investment  Agreements.  G-­‐  24  Discussion  Paper  Nº  58,  Washington  D.C.     -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   (2010b).   US-­‐South   Korea   Free   Trade   Agreement:   Out   of   Control.   Published  

by  

the  

Guardian  

UK  

on  

July  

1,  

2010  

(http://www.guardian.co.uk/profile/kevingallagher).     Grabel,  I.  (2010).  Capital  Controls:  “The  new  normal”  (Part  I  and  II).  At  the  Triple   Crisis  Blog  http://triplecrisis.com/capital-­‐controls/     Helleiner,   E.   (2009).   The   Contemporary   Reform   of   Global   Financial   Governance:   Implications  of  and  Lessons  from  the  Past.  G24  Discussion  Paper,  Washington  DC.  

 

53  

-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐  and  S.  Pagliari  (2008).  Towards  the  G20  Summit:  From  Financial  Crisis   to   International   Regulatory   Reform.   The   Centre   for   International   Governance   Innovation  (CIGI).  Policy  Brief  9,  October   Hoekman,  B.  and  M.  Kostecki  (2009).  The  Political  Economy  of  the  World  Trading   System.  Oxford  University  Press,  Third  Edition.   Kim,  K.;  Kim,  B-­‐K.  and  Suh,  Y.  (2009).  Opening  to  Capital  Flows  and  Implications  for   Korea.  IMER  Working  Paper,  Bank  of  Korea.     -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐  (undated).  Global  Financial  Crisis  and  Korean  Economy.  Mimeo.   Kim,   Ch.   (2010).   Coping   with   volatile   capital   flows   –   Korea´s   Experience   and   the   challenges   ahead.   Speech   by   Mr   Choongsoo   Kim,   Governor   of   the   Bank   of   Korea,   at   the  European  Chamber  of  Commerce  in  Korea  (EUCCK)  Annual  Seminar,  Seoul,  27   October.     Lee,  K.;  G.  Kim;  H-­‐K  Kim  and  H-­‐S  Song  (2010).  A  New  Macro-­‐Financial  System  for  a   Stable   and   Crisis-­‐resilient   Growth   in   Korea.   Seoul   Journal   of   Economics,   Vol.   23   Nº2.     Lee,   K-­‐K   (2010).   The   Post-­‐Crisis   Change   in   the   Financial   System   in   Korea:   Problems   of   Neoliberal   Restructuring   and   Financial   Opening   After   1997.   Third   World  Network  –  TWN,  Global  Economy  Series  20.     Levy   Yeyati,   E.;   S.L.   Schmukler   and   N.   van   Horen   (2008).   Crises,   Capital   Controls   and   Financial   Integration.   The   World   Bank,   Development   Economics   Research   Group,  Policy  Research  Working  Paper  4770.   Lyons,   G.   (2010).   Capital   controls   can   deter   short-­‐term   speculation.   FT.com/beyondbrics.   Manger,   M.   S.   (2009).   Investing   in   Protection:   The   Politics   of   Preferential   Trade   Agreements  between  North  and  South.  Cambridge.     Moguillansky,  G.;  R.  Studart  and  S.  Vergara  (2004).  Foreign  Banks  in  Latin  America:   a  paradoxical  result.  CEPAL  Review  82,  April.    

54  

Mortimore,   M.   and   L.   Stanley   (2009).   Justice   Denied:   Dispute   Settlement   in   Latin   America’s   Trade   and   Investment   Agreements.   Discussion   Paper   Nº   27,   Working   Group  on  Development  and  Environment  in  the  Americas.   Ocampo,   J.   A.   (2010).   Reforming   the   International   Monetary   and   Financial   Architecture.   Lecture   Outline.   WIDER   Annual   Lecture   14,   UN   Headquarters,   December  9.     Ostry,   J.;   A.   Ghosh,   K.;   K.   Habermeier;   M.   Chamon;   M:   Qureshi;   and,   D.   Reinhardt   (2010).  Capital  Inflows:  The  Role  of  Controls.  IMF  Staff  Position  Note,  February  19,   2010  SPN/10/04.   Peterson,  

L.  

(2009).  

Whither  

the  

New  

Financial  

Claims?  

http://kluwerarbitrationblog.com/       Public   Citizens   (2009).   No   Meaningful   Safeguards   for   Prudential   Regulation   Measures   in   World   Trade   Organization´s   Financial   Services   Deregulation   Agreement.   http://www.citizen.org/documents/PrudentialMeasuresReportFINAL.pdf     Raghavan,   C.   (2009).   Financial   Services,   the   WTO   and   Initiatives   for   Global   Financial  Reform.  G24  Discussion  Paper,  Washington  DC.     Ree,  

L.  

(2010).  

The  

Consequences  

of  

Market  

Intervention.  

http://kluwerarbitrationblog.com/       Schott,   J.   (2007).   The   Korea-­‐US   Free   Trade   Agreement:   A   Summary   Assessement.   Peterson  Institute  for  International  Economics,  Policy  Brief   Singh,   K.   (2010).   Emerging   markets   consider   capital   controls   to   regulate   speculative   capital   flows.   VOX   Research-­‐based   policy   analysis   and   commentary   from  leading  economists,  5th  July.     Stalling,   B.   (2006).   Financiamiento   para   el   Desarrollo:   América   Latina   desde   una   perspectiva  comparada.  CEPAL   Stanley,  L.  (2004).  “”.  CEPAL,  Santiago  de  Chile.      

55  

-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   (2009).   Resolución   de   conflictos   en   material   de   bonos   soberanos:   una   “crítica”  Mirada  institucional  al  papel  del  CIADI.  Nuevos  Documentos  CEDES  Nº  58.     Stiglitz,  

J.  

(2002).  

Globalism’s  

Discontents.  

American  

Prospect,  

http://www.thirworldtraveler.com/Global_Economy/Globalisms_Discontents.htm l     -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   (2004).   Capital   –   Market   Liberalization,   Globalization,   and   the   IMF.   Oxford  Review  of  Economic  Policy,  Vol.  20  Nº1.     -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   (2010).   Financial   Regulation.   Article   at   FM.co.za   (available   at   http://www0.gsb.columbia.edu/ipd/index.cfm)     Tarullo,   D.   (2008).   Banking   on   Basel:   The   Future   of   International   Financial   Regulation.  Peterson  Institute  for  International  Economics.   TIME   (2010).   Are   Capital   Controls   good   for   the   world   economy?   Wednesday,   October  27.   Third  World  Network  –  TWN  (2010).  Financial  Crisis  and  Trade  Agreements,  Draft   Preliminary  Note.  TWN  Briefing  Paper  (http://www.twnside.org.sd)      Tucker,   T.   and   L.   Wallach   (2009).   No   Meaningful   Safeguards   for   Prudential   Measures   in   World   Trade   Organization’s   Financial   Services   Deregulation   Agreements.  Special  Pittsburgh  G-­‐20  Report,  September.     Turner,   A.   (2010).   After   the   crises:   assessing   the   costs   and   benefits   of   financial   liberalization.   Speech   at   the   14th   Chintaman   Deshmukh   Memorial   Lecture,   Reserve   Bank  

of  

India,  

Mumbai  

(http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pages/Library/Communication/Speeches/2010/0215_at. shtml).       U.S.   Department   of   State   (2009).   Report   of   the   Sub-­‐Committee   of   the   ACIEP   regarding  the  model  BIT.  September  30th,  2009.   USITC   (2010).   U.S.   –   Korea   Free   Trade   Agreement:   Potential   Economy-­‐wide   and   Selected   Sectoral   Effects.   United   States   International   Trade   Commission,    

56  

Investigation  No.  TA-­‐2104-­‐24  USTIC  Publication  3949,  September  2007.  Corrected   New  Printing  March  2010.     Van   Aaken,   A.   (2008).   Perils   of   Success?   The   Case   of   International   Investment   Protection.  European  Business  Organization  Law  Review  ):  1-­‐27.   -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   and   J.   Kurtz   (2009).   The   Global   Financial   Crisis   and   International   Economic   Law.   University   of   St.   Gallen   Law   School,   Law   and   Economic   Research   Paper  Series.  Working  Paper  Nº  2009-­‐04,  June.     Wade,   R.   (2009).   From   Global   Imbalances   to   Global   Reorganizations.   Cambridge   Journal  of  Economics,  33,  539-­‐562.   WTO  (2010a).  Financial  Services   –  Other  Business.  Note  by  the  Secretariat.  WTO,   S/FIN/M/62   -­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐-­‐   (2010b).   Financial   Services   –   Background   Note   by   the   Secretariat.   WTO   Committee  on  Trade  in  Financial  Services  S/FIN/M/63   Yi,  I.;  S.  Miller  and  Y.  Jeon  (2009).  The  Effects  of  Increased  Foreign  Ownership  on   Korean  Domestic  Banks.  The  Journal  of  the  Korean  Economy,  Vol.  10,  Nº1  (April)   127-­‐150.  

 

57  

7.  Annex:  Tables  and  Graphs     Table  1:  Argentina  and  Korea  Republic,  basic  indicators  (1980-­‐2010)   Argentina      

Year  

GDP  Current  Prices                               GDP  per  capita   (U$  Dollars,   (U$  Dollars)   Billions)  

    1980   1981   1982   1983   1984   1985   1986   1987   1988   1989   1990   1991   1992   1993   1994   1995   1996   1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003   2004   2005   2006   2007   2008   2009   2010  e  

209.005   169.749   84.292   103.983   116.751   88.182   106.038   108.718   127.343   81.701   141.329   189.583   228.763   236.491   257.425   258.017   272.219   292.988   299.080   283.761   284.540   269.098   102.723   129.544   153.005   183.001   214.042   262.041   328.028   310.057   351.015   Source:  IMF  

 

7.477,83   5.966,58   2.913,66   3.544,07   3.912,58   2.905,51   3.449,53   3.496,89   4.046,48   2.564,37   4.344,56   5.750,17   6.845,08   6.972,55   7.493,51   7.418,73   7.734,46   8.229,00   8.306,54   7.795,95   7.735,45   7.242,35   2.738,14   3.420,78   4.002,64   4.741,91   5.492,40   6.658,16   8.253,18   7.725,46   8.662,99  

Korea       Current  Account   Balance                                GDP  Current  Prices                GDP                    p    er  capita   (U$  Dollars,   (U$  Dollars,  Billions)   (U$  Dollars)   Billions)  

-­‐2.573   -­‐5.721   -­‐2.917   -­‐2.436   -­‐2.495   -­‐1   -­‐2.859   -­‐4.235   -­‐1.572   1.095   4.665   0   -­‐6.468   -­‐8.043   -­‐10.981   -­‐5.104   -­‐6.754   -­‐12.118   -­‐14.467   -­‐11.909   -­‐8.955   -­‐3.782   8.768   8.142   2.658   4.700   6.772   5.923   4.807   6.189   6.016  

64.385   72.399   77.524   85.962   94.945   98.502   113.737   143.378   192.113   236.233   270.405   315.575   338.171   372.209   435.590   531.139   573.001   532.239   357.510   461.808   533.385   504.584   575.930   643.760   721.976   844.866   951.773   1.049.239   931.405   832.512   986.256  

1.689   1.870   1.971   2.154   2.350   2.414   2.760   3.445   4.571   5.565   6.308   7.289   7.730   8.422   9.757   11.779   12.587   11.582   7.724   9.906   11.347   10.655   12.094   13.451   15.029   17.551   19.707   21.653   19.162   17.074   20.165  

Current  Account   Balance                               (U$  Dollars,   Billions)  

-­‐5.312   -­‐4.607   -­‐2.551   -­‐1.524   -­‐1.293   -­‐1   4.709   10.058   14.505   5.344   -­‐2.014   -­‐8.417   -­‐4.095   1   -­‐4.024   -­‐8.665   -­‐23.120   -­‐8.287   40.371   24.522   12.251   8.033   5.394   11.950   28.174   14.981   5.385   5.876   -­‐5.776   42.668   26.041  

58  

Table  2:  Financial  repression  and  financial  liberalization,  Argentina  and  Korea  compared   Domestic  Financial   Country   Capital  Account   Sector   Stock  Market   Liberalization  Index   Argentina   Apr  76  -­‐  Nov  78  PL   Jan  77  -­‐  May  82  FL   Jan  77  -­‐  Feb  82  PL   Jan  77  -­‐  Nov  78  PL     Dec  78  -­‐  Feb  82  FL   Jun  82  -­‐  Sep  87  R   Mar  82  -­‐  Dec  88  R   Dec  78    -­‐  Dec  88  R     Mar  82  -­‐  Nov  89  R   Oct  87  -­‐  Oct  01  FL   Jan  89  -­‐  Oct  01  FL   Jan  89  -­‐  May  91  R     Dec  89  -­‐  Oct  01  FL   Nov  01  -­‐  Nov  02  R   Nov  01  -­‐  Jun  04  R   Jan  89  -­‐  Nov  89  PL     Feb  02  -­‐  Mar  03  PL   Dec  02  -­‐  FL   Jul  04  FL   Dec  89  -­‐  Oct  01  FL     Apr  03  -­‐  May  05  FL       Nov  01  -­‐  Nov  02  R     Jun  05  -­‐  PL       Dec  02  -­‐  Jun  04  PL           Jul  04  FL   Korea   Jan  93  -­‐  Dec  95  (PL)   Jan  88  -­‐  Dec  94  (PL)   Jan  91  -­‐  Apr  98  PL   Jan  93  -­‐  Dec  95  PL     Jan  96  (FL)   Jan  95  (FL)   May  98  FL   Jan  96  FL  

Source:  Smuckler   Notes:  (R)  Financial  repression;  (PL),  Partial  Liberalization  (FL)  Full  Liberalization.     Table  3:  Bank  regulation,  supervisory  activities  and  self-­‐regulating  monitoring  (at  1999)   Concept     Capital  Requirement     Risk  -­‐  Adjusted  Capital  ratio   Capital       Index  of  bank     Index  of  banking  activities     Regulatory  Index  -­‐  General   Supervision  power  -­‐  Index     Immediate  correction  index     Restructuration  power  index     Solvency  declaration  index     Indulgency  index     Supervision  Index  -­‐  General   Certificate  auditing     International  Rating  Agencies     Bank  board  qualification     Divulgation  index     Deposit  assurance  index     Subordinated  debt  index   Private  monitoring  index    

Ratio   %       (0-­‐6)   (0-­‐3)   (0-­‐4)       (0-­‐16)   (0-­‐6)   (0-­‐3)   (0-­‐3)   (0-­‐4)       (0-­‐1)   (0-­‐1)   (0-­‐1)   (0-­‐3)   (0-­‐1)   (0-­‐1)      

ARG   11,5   16,4   6,0   2,0   1,8   37,7   12,0   0,0   3,0   2,0   3,0   20,0   1,0   1,0   1,0   2,0   0,0   1,0   6,0  

KOR   8,0   9,3   5,0   1,0   2,3   25,5   10,0   4,0   3,0   2,0   1,0   20,0   1,0   1,0   1,0   3,0   0,0   1,0   7,0  

Source:  Stalling  (2004)            

 

59  

&) *' &) % *& &) % *" &) % *( &) % *+ &) % *$ &) % *, &) % ** &) % *&) % *) &) % -' &) % -& &) % -" &) % -( &) % -+ &) % -$ &) % -, &) % -* &) % -&) % -) &) % )' &) % )& &) % )" &) % )( &) % )+ &) % )$ &) % ), &) % )* &) % )&) % )) "' % '' "' % '& "' % '" "' % '( "' % '+ "' % '$ "' % ', "' % '* "' % '%

Graph  1:  Chin  –  Ito  Capital  Account  Index   (%

"#

%$"%

&#

%$&%

'#

%$'%

!'#

%$!&%

!&#

%$!"%

!"#

%$   !"#

%$./0% 12/%

Source:  Chin  

60