BIS Working Papers No 646
Macroprudential policy and bank risk by Yener Altunbas, Mahir Binici and Leonardo
Gambacorta
Monetary and Economic Department June 2017
JEL classification: E43, E58, G18, G28 Keywords: macroprudential policies, effectiveness, bank risk
BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS.
This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org).
©
Bank for International Settlements 2017. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated.
ISSN 1020-0959 (print) ISSN 1682-7678 (online)
Macroprudential policy and bank risk
Yener Altunbas, Mahir Binici and Leonardo Gambacorta
Abstract This paper investigates the effects of macroprudential policies on bank risk through a large panel of banks operating in 61 advanced and emerging market economies. There are three main findings. First, there is evidence suggesting that macroprudential tools have a significant impact on bank risk. Second, the responses to changes in macroprudential tools differ among banks, depending on their specific balance sheet characteristics. In particular, banks that are small, weakly capitalised and with a higher share of wholesale funding react more strongly to changes in macroprudential tools. Third, controlling for bank-specific characteristics, macroprudential policies are more effective in a tightening than in an easing episode.
JEL classification: E43, E58, G18, G28. Keywords: macroprudential policies, effectiveness, bank risk.
University of Wales Bangor, e-mail:
[email protected]
Central Bank of Turkey, e-mail:
[email protected]
Bank for International Settlements (BIS) and CEPR, e-mail:
[email protected]. Corresponding author We thank Claudio Borio, Stijn Claessens, Iftekhar Hasan, Andres Murcia, Luiz Pereira da Silva, Hyun Shin, Elod Takats and participants at the 2016 IFABS conference in Barcelona, the 4th Bordeaux workshop in international economics and finance and the 6th BIS-SNB research workshop for useful comments and suggestions. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bank for International Settlements or of the Central Bank of Turkey.
1
1. Introduction Prior to the global financial crisis (GFC) financial stability was mainly considered from a microprudential perspective. The aim of supervisory policy was to reduce the risk that individual institutions would fail, without any explicit regard for their impact on the financial system as a whole or on the overall economy. Lehman Brothers’ default reminded us that financial stability has a macroprudential or systemic dimension that cannot be ignored. Treating the financial system as merely the sum of its parts leads one to overlook the system’s historical tendency to swing from boom to bust. Nowadays, financial stability is considered from a macroprudential perspective. However, the implementation of a new macroprudential framework for financial stability raises a number of challenges. A first challenge is the evaluation of the effectiveness of macroprudential policies, especially when more than one tool is activated. Moreover, effectiveness should be analysed with respect to the specific goal that macroprudential policies are designed to achieve; that is, to increase the resilience of the financial system, or, more ambitiously, to tame financial booms and busts. At the moment, the evidence is mixed and most research focuses on analysing the impact of macroprudential tools on bank lending (as an intermediate target), not directly on bank risk (the limitation of which is the ultimate goal). For instance, recent evidence suggests that debt-to-income ratios and, probably to a lesser extent, loan-to-value ratios are comparatively more effective than capital requirements as tools for containing credit growth (Claessens et al, 2013). Indeed, the recent activation of the Basel III countercyclical capital buffer to risk-weighted domestic residential mortgages in Switzerland, though having had some effect on mortgage pricing, seems to have had little impact on credit extension (Basten and Koch, 2015). But the main goal of the Basel III buffers is to increase the resilience of the banking system, not to smooth the credit cycle. Restraining the boom is perhaps no more than a welcome, potential side effect (Drehmann and Gambacorta, 2012). A second challenge pertains to the varied nature of macroprudential objectives and instruments. In this area, there is no one-size-fits-all approach. Which tools to use, how to calibrate them and when to deploy them will all depend on how the authorities view the vulnerabilities involved and how confident they are in their analysis. The legal and institutional setup will also be relevant. A given instrument’s effects depend on a variety of factors, which have to be assessed against the chosen objective. Some instruments may work better to achieve the narrow aim of increasing financial system resilience rather than the broader aim of constraining the cycle. For instance, countercyclical capital buffers aim to build cushions against banks’ total credit exposures, whereas loan-to-value ratio caps only affect new borrowers (and usually only those that are highly leveraged). This argues in favour of capital buffers if the objective is to improve overall resilience. However, loan-to-value ratios may be more effective if the aim is to curb specific types of credit extension. Third, most macroprudential policies aim at containing systemic risk, a type of risk that is by nature endogenous. By using macroprudential tools, policymakers aim at limiting bank risk-taking and the probability of the occurrence of a financial crisis. This means that – ideally – we should also be interested in how these policies influence a bank’s contribution to systemwide risk. Measurement of systemic risk is, however, still rudimentary, although some concepts have been developed (measures such as CoVaR, stress testing and Shapley values).
2
A first step could be to evaluate how macroprudential tools impact specific measures of bank risk, such as the expected default frequency (EDF) or the Z-score. The calculation of the EDF indicator requires bank issuance of equity on the stock market, while the Z-score is an indicator of the probability of default which relies on balance sheet variables. This paper complements other studies on the effectiveness of macroprudential policies.1 Its main contribution is to analyses the effectiveness of such policies on bank risk in a comprehensive way, exploiting the cross-sectional dimension among countries. Interestingly, the more advanced economies tended to ignore the macroprudential dimension in the runup to the crisis. Emerging market economies (EMEs) were generally better aware of the need to think about the financial system as a whole, and more willing to intervene in response to evidence of a build-up of imbalances and risks (Figure 1). All this means that it is necessary to pool information for a large number of banks operating in both advanced countries and EMEs, and to control for different institutional setups and time-specific factors affecting the risktaking channel. In other words, pooling information regarding countries with different experiences in the use of macroprudential tools greatly reduces concerns about possible omitted variables (Demirguc-Kunt et al, 2013). Using information for 3,177 banks operating in both advanced economies and EMEs over the period 1990–2012, we find that macroprudential tools – both those focusing on dampening the cycle (ie loan to value ratios, reserve and currency requirements) and those specifically designed to enhance banks’ resilience (ie capital requirements) – have a significant impact on bank risk. We also find that the responses to changes in macroprudential tools differ among banks, depending on their specific balance sheet characteristics. In particular, banks that are small, weakly capitalised and with a higher share of wholesale funding react more strongly to changes in macroprudential tools. Finally, macroprudential policies are more effective in a tightening than an easing cycle. The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. The next section discusses how macroprudential policies can impact bank risk. Section III describes the identification strategy and data used in our analysis, while Section IV and V present the main results and robustness checks. The last section summarises our main conclusions.
2. Macroprudential policy and bank risk Following a widely accepted definition, “macroprudential policies are designed to identify and mitigate risks to systemic stability, in turn reducing the cost to the economy from a disruption in financial services that underpin the workings of financial markets - such as the provision of credit, but also of insurance and payment and settlement services” (FSB/IMF/BIS, 2009). However, providing a framework for the relationship between macroprudential policies and systemic risk is not straightforward. The need for macroprudential policies arises from two dimensions of systemic risk: the time and cross-sectional dimensions. The time dimension represents the need to constrain financial booms (Borio, 2014). Such financial booms can originate from both the supply and demand sides of agents, and financial 1
For an overview of the existing empirical evidence on the effectiveness of macroprudential policies see, amongst others, Claessens (2015).
3
intermediary behaviour. For example, the amplification mechanism known as “financial accelerator” is mainly related to the demand side (Claessens et al, 2013). But other mechanisms are related to the supply side, as in the model of Adrian and Shin (2010, 2014), where an initial positive shock that boosts the value of a bank’s assets, such as loans and securities, could induce a further increase in debt if the bank targets a certain leverage ratio. Banks’ decisions on leverage and the composition of assets and/or liabilities could make them more vulnerable to future negative shocks through balance sheet mismatches. The second feature of systemic risk is its cross-sectional dimension, which is mainly related to the interconnectedness of financial institutions. This aspect became the focus of policy discussion after the GFC as specific shocks to some institutions were heavily amplified by spreading across financial markets and countries. The new Basel III regulatory framework, for instance, which targets systemically important financial institutions (SIFI) with specific capital surcharges, aims to reduce negative externalities stemming from interconnectedness. The risk-taking behaviour of banks, thus, could be mitigated by the active use of macroprudential policies. For instance, capital-based instruments, such as capital conservation buffers, would allow institutions to accumulate capital in good times, which could then be used to absorb losses in stress periods. Similarly, the countercyclical capital buffer could be actively used to “achieve the broader macro-prudential goal of protecting the banking sector from periods of excess credit growth.” (BCBS, 2010, pp 5). In addition, provisioning requirements, such as the dynamic provisioning tool used in Spain, also require banks to adjust the total amount of loss provisions when their profits are growing, with the aim of being able to draw on these provisions during an economic downturn. Therefore, the collective use of capital-based requirements could mitigate bank risk by requiring higher buffers during an upturn. Bank risk could be further mitigated by the use of other macroprudential tools during an upturn. For instance, increasing liquidity requirements and imposing stringent currency instruments could minimise bank risk emanating from repricing and liquidity gaps, as well as exchange rate fluctuations. Therefore, single or multiple uses of macroprudential instruments are expected to have an impact on the EDF or Z-score of banks, two alternative measures or bank risk used in this study. Besides the direct effect of macroprudential tools on bank risk, monetary policy also has an impact on risk-taking and financial stability (Gambacorta, 2009; Borio and Zhu, 2014; Altunbas et al, 2014; Dell’Ariccia et al, 2010). A prolonged period of low interest rates could impact risk-taking in two different ways. The first is through the search for yield (Rajan, 2005). Low interest rates may increase incentives for asset managers to take on more risks for contractual, behavioural or institutional reasons. For example, in 2003–2004, many investors shifted from low-risk government bonds to higher-yielding but also to riskier corporate and EME bonds. A similar mechanism was detected in the theoretical model designed by Dell’Ariccia et al (2010): monetary easing leads to a reduction in the interest rate on bank loans, which, in turn, reduces a bank’s gross return, conditional on its portfolio. This reduces the bank’s incentive to monitor its loans, and the real yield on safe (monitored) assets, thus banks will typically increase their demand for risky assets.
4
The second way in which low interest rates could encourage banks to take on more risk is through their impact on valuations, incomes and cash flows.2 A reduction in the policy rate boosts asset and collateral values, which in turn can modify bank estimates of probabilities of default, losses given default and volatilities. For example, by increasing asset prices, low interest rates tend to reduce volatility and thus risk perceptions: since a higher stock price increases the value of equity relative to corporate debt, a sharp increase in stock prices reduces corporate leverage and could thus decrease the risk of holding stocks.3 This example can be applied to the widespread use of Value-at-Risk methodologies for economic and regulatory capital purposes (Danielsson et al, 2004). As volatility tends to decline in rising markets, it releases the risk budgets of financial firms and encourages position-taking. A similar argument is made in the model of Adrian and Shin (2009), who stress that changes in measured risk determine adjustments in bank balance sheets and leverage conditions, and, in turn, amplify business cycle movements.4 Macroprudential tools could, in principle, be used to moderate the risk-taking incentives arising from monetary policy decisions. For instance, Igan and Kang (2011) argue that the impact of a tightening of monetary policy on defaults can be contained by having in place conservative limits on debt-to-income (DTI) ratios. On the other hand, macroprudential measures, such as limits on LTV ratios, can reduce vulnerabilities under the condition that accommodative monetary policy is driving up asset prices. Additionally, higher capital requirements (including countercyclical) or tighter leverage and liquidity ratios may help contain increases in bank risks in response to expected lax monetary policy (see Farhi and Tirole, 2012; IMF, 2013). To complement the theoretical discussions outlined above and individual country studies, the analysis in this paper controls for monetary policy conditions and a broader set of country- and bank-specific characteristics.
3. Model, identification strategy and data The baseline empirical model is given by the following equation, adapted from Altunbas et al (2014):
Risk i ,k ,t Risk i ,k ,t 1 EDF _ NFk ,t MPk ,t M C k ,t BSCi ,k ,t 1 i k ,t i ,k ,t
(1)
2
This is close in spirit to the familiar financial accelerator, in which increases in collateral values reduce borrowing constraints (Bernanke et al, 1996). Adrian and Shin (2009) claim that the risk-taking channel differs from and strengthens the financial accelerator because it focuses on amplification mechanisms created by financing frictions in the banking sector. See also Borio and Zhu (2014).
3
For this reason, the link between asset prices and asset price volatility is sometimes described as the leverage effect. See, amongst others, Pagan and Schwert (1990) and the studies cited in Bollerslev et al (1992).
4
Risk-taking may also be influenced by the communication policies of a central bank and the characteristics of policymakers’ reaction functions. For example, a high degree of central bank predictability with regard to future policy decisions can reduce market uncertainty and thus lead banks to take on more risks. Moreover, agents’ perception that the central bank will ease monetary policy in the event of adverse economic outcomes could lower the probability of large downside risks, thereby producing an insurance effect. For this reason, Diamond and Rajan (2012) argue that, in order to diminish banks’ incentive to take on liquidity risk, monetary policy should be kept tighter in good times than strictly necessary based on current economic conditions.
5
with i=1,…, N , k= 1, …,K and t=1, …, T, where i is the bank, k is the country and t is time. Table 1 reports the summary statistics for the variables used and the relevant sources. The final database includes 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries.5 More information at the country level is provided in Annex A. In the baseline equation (1), the annual change of the risk measure (∆Risk) for bank i, headquartered in country k, in year t, is regressed on its own lag and EDF change for the nonfinancial sector in country k (∆EDF_NF). This variable aims at filtering out the effects of changes in the market price of risk due to the business cycle. MP indicates the change in the macroprudential tool, which could be the change in an aggregate index, as in Cerutti et al (2017), or a complete vector of macroprudential tools. BSC and MC represent, respectively, additional bank-specific characteristics and macro variables that are introduced to disentangle the risk-taking channel from other mechanisms at work. In particular, the vector MC includes a measure for the monetary policy stance (DIFF, the difference between the real interest rate and the natural rate) and the growth rate of nominal GDP (GDP).6 We also include time invariant bank fixed effects ( i ) and a dummy variable ( k ,t ) that takes the value of 1 in those specific years in which countries experienced a banking crisis and zero elsewhere (Valencia and Laeven, 2012).
3.1 Measurement of bank risk By setting macroprudential tools, policymakers aim to limit bank risk-taking and the probability of the occurrence of a financial crisis. This means that – ideally – we should measure how macroprudential policies influence a bank’s contribution to system-wide risk. Measurement of systemic risk is, however, still rudimentary, although some concepts have been developed (CoVaR, stress testing and Shapley value measures). A compromise could be to evaluate how macroprudential tools impact specific measures of bank risk. In the baseline model, the dependent variable is given by the change in the EDF (∆EDF), representing the probability that a bank will default within a given time horizon (typically one year). EDF is a well-known, forward-looking indicator of risk, computed by Moody’s KMV, which builds on Merton’s model to price corporate bond debt (Merton, 1974). The EDF value, expressed as a percentage, is calculated by combining banks’ financial statements with stock market information and Moody’s proprietary default database. We also checked the robustness of the results by using change in the Z-score as an alternative measure of bank risk. 7 We mitigate the effects of outliers by dropping the first and the last percentile of the
5
We control for mergers and acquisitions in the following way. If a bank A and a bank B are merged in a bank C, we consider bank A and bank B as different financial intermediaries until the date of the merger and then we include a new bank C. In case a bank D acquires a bank E, we include Bank E in the database until the date of the acquisition, and we drop the yearobservation for bank E in which the acquisition took place. After excluding the presence of outliers, excluding information in the first and last percentile of the distribution, 20,870 observations and 3,177 banks remained.
6
Similar results (not reported) are obtained by including in the specification both the growth rate of real GDP and the inflation rate. The Z-score can be summarised as Z=(k+ROA)/σROA, where k is equity capital as percent of assets, ROA is the average aftertax return as a percent of assets, and σROA is the standard deviation of the after-tax return on assets, as a proxy for return volatility. The Z-score measures the number of standard deviations a return realisation has to fall in order to deplete equity, under the assumption of normality of bank returns. A higher Z-score corresponds to a lower upper bound of insolvency risk, therefore it implies a lower probability of insolvency risk. For an application, see amongst others, Laeven and Levine (2009).
7
6
distribution of the variables. Figure 2 shows that the cross-sectional dispersion of banks’ EDFs and Z-scores (both measured by means of the coefficient of variation) is not concentrated in the period of the GFC. This means that there were already significant differences in bank risk at the cross-sectional level prior to the crisis. Interestingly the cross-sectional dispersion of the Z-score is also very high in relation to the early 1990s’ recession and associated banking crisis. In Table 2, banks are grouped depending on their specific risk position, using one-year EDF values. For the bank-specific characteristics, we use bank-level data from BankScope, a commercial database maintained by Fitch and Bureau van Dijk. A ”high-risk” bank has the average EDF of banks included in the tenth decile (ie in the 10% of the riskier banks with an average EDFH equal to 7.4%); a ”low-risk” bank has the average EDF of the banks in the first decile (EDFL is equal to 0.07%). The first part of the table shows that high-risk banks are less strongly capitalised. The lower level of capitalisation appears to be consistent with the higher perceived risk of these banks. Additionally, low-risk banks make relatively more loans than high-risk banks, and are more efficient (have a lower cost-to-income ratio). Bank profitability, measured by return on assets (ROA), is higher and more stable for lowrisk banks. This result is probably due to the inclusion of the GFC period in the sample. The coefficient of variation of the ROA, calculated using information for the four quarters ahead, for low-risk bank is indeed half (one quarter) with respect to high-risk banks, considering the EDF (Z-score) as a measure of risk. It is worth noting that banks with a lower Z-score are more risky, while banks with a lower EDF are less risky. To compare the signs of the coefficients in the regressions, we therefore multiply the Z-score by -1. Using this approach, a higher level of the two indicators (Z-score and EDF) is always associated with more risky banks.
3.2 Macroprudential policy indicators The construction of macroprudential policy indicators involves a number of steps. First, we consider an aggregate index that allows us to evaluate the overall effectiveness of macroprudential tools when more than one measure is activated. This aggregate index represents a very rough approximation because macroprudential tools may be very different in nature. For example, we may need to consider a case where the minimum loan to value ratio was increased while, contemporaneously, reserve ratios were reduced. To deal with this kind of situation, we first consider a dummy that takes the value of +1 if a given macroprudential tool was tightened and -1 if it was eased, leaving zero elsewhere. Then, following Kuttner and Shim (2013), we calculate an aggregate macroprudential indicator (MP_indexk,t) that sums up all the different dummies for the various macroprudential tools. This means that, if multiple actions in the same direction are taken within a given year, the variable could take on the values of 2 or –2, or even 3 and –3. It also means that a tightening action and a loosening action taken within the same year could cancel each other out. This indicator weights each tool in the same way and will be considered in our baseline regression. Second, we recognise that the macroprudential toolkit tends to be large, as it combines an array of different instruments. In particular, we distinguish them according to the following five categories: a) capital-based instruments; b) liquidity-based instruments; c) asset-side
7
instruments; d) reserve requirements; and e) currency requirements. Table 3 provides an overview of these categories (with further information in Annex B). Third, the purpose of the various policies could differ. For instance, some instruments are intended to increase directly the financial sector’s resilience, while others focus on dampening the cycle as an intermediate target. In that respect, the effects of specific macroprudential tools on credit growth and bank risk can be different. Borio (2011) and Claessens et al (2013) distinguish between the goals and the types of policy that are commonly used. Macroprudential tools with the main objective of enhancing the financial sector’s resilience include countercyclical capital requirements, leverage restrictions, general or dynamic provisioning, and the establishment of liquidity requirements, among others. Within the category of macroprudential tools aimed at dampening the credit cycle, Claessens et al (2013) include changes in reserve requirements, variations in limits on foreign currency mismatches, cyclical adjustments to loan-loss provisioning, and margins or haircuts. Other macroprudential policy aims include reducing the effects of contagion or shock propagation from SIFIs or networks. This group might also include policies, such as capital surcharges linked to systemic risk, restrictions on asset composition or activities. Using the categorisation presented in Borio (2011) and Claessens et al (2013), we classify policies according to their purpose. In particular, policies to dampen the cycle – ie those used by authorities countercyclically to dampen an expected credit boom or credit crunch – are identified with by term cyclical (we refer to the categories (c), (d) and (e) in Table 3). Macroprudential tools with a more structural objective, which are intended to increase the resilience of the financial sector (such as capital, liquidity or provisioning requirements), are identified with by the term resilience (categories (a) and (b) in Table 3). The chart pie on the left-hand side of Figure 3 splits the different types of macroprudential policy adopted in the period 1990–2014. Interestingly, only one quarter of policies are aimed at improving the resilience of the financial sector using capital, liquidity of provisioning requirements (slices in blue colour). By contrast, the vast majority have the purpose of dampening the cycle – ie those used by the authorities countercyclically to dampen an expected credit boom or credit crunch. More than half are represented by changes in reserve requirements. Finally, we split the changes in macroprudential tools into easing and tightening cases. In this way, we can verify the asymmetric effects of each tool. The chart pie on the right-hand side of Figure 3 shows that in three quarters of cases macroprudential tools were tightened. The dummy MP_easing (MP_tightening) takes a value of 1 if the macroprudential tool was eased (tightened) in a given year and zero elsewhere. This specification is particularly important to check our results against the existing literature. Cerutti et al (2017), for example, find some evidence of the asymmetric impact of macroprudential policies, claiming that those policies seem more effective when credit growth rates are very high, but have a less positive impact during busts. Similarly, Claessens et al (2013) find that macroprudential policies help mitigate asset growth, with the effects largely present during the boom (implying that the tightening measures are more effective). Finally, Kuttner and Shim (2013) find that three of the four macroprudential policies analysed in their study have statistically significant effects on housing credit when measures are tightened but not loosened. However, they find similar but weaker asymmetric responses when they assess the impact of macroprudential policies on house prices.
8
3.3 Bank-specific characteristics In order to discriminate between loan supply and demand movements, the bank lending channel literature has focused on cross-sectional differences across banks. This strategy relies on the hypothesis that certain bank-specific characteristics (for example, bank size, liquidity, capitalisation and funding composition) only influence loan supply while a bank’s loan demand is largely independent of these factors. Broadly speaking, this approach assumes that, after a monetary tightening, the drop in the total availability of funding, which affects banks’ ability to make new loans or their ability to shield their loan portfolios, differs among banks. Drawing on this literature, we analyse macroprudential tools in the same way as monetary policy changes. Using the BankScope database, we therefore include four bank-specific characteristics that could influence bank supply shifts in the case of macroprudential policy changes. The first three are: bank size, proxied by the logarithm of a bank’s total assets (SIZE), the liquidity ratio (LIQ) and the capital to asset ratio (CAP). These give insightful information, not only on banks’ ability to insulate loan supply from monetary and macroprudential shocks (Kashyap and Stein, 2000; Kishan and Opiela, 2000; Gambacorta, 2005) but also control for “too big to fail” considerations, differences in business models and capital regulation effects. The fourth indicator is the share of deposits over total liabilities (DEP), a measure of a bank’s contractual strength. Banks with a large amount of deposits will adjust their deposit rates by less (and less quickly) than banks whose liabilities are mainly composed of variable rate bonds that are directly affected by market movements (Berlin and Mester, 1999). Intuitively, this should mean that, in view of the presence of menu costs, it is more likely that a bank will adjust its terms for passive deposits if the conditions relating to its own alternative form of refinancing (ie bonds) change. Moreover, a bank will refrain from changing deposit conditions because, if the ratio of deposits to total liabilities is high, even small changes to their price will have a substantial effect on total interest rate costs. By contrast, banks that use relatively more bonds than deposits for financing purposes come under greater pressure because their costs increase contemporaneously with market rates (and to a similar extent). Finally, the ratio of bank deposits over total liabilities is also influenced by the existence of deposit insurance, which makes this form of funding more stable and less exposed to the risk of a run. Acharya and Mora (2015) report that banks may actively manage the deposit to total funding ratio by changing deposit rates. To draw a parallel with the bank lending channel literature, it is interesting to investigate whether the responses to macroprudential shocks differ by type of bank. To test for this, we introduce interactions terms that are the products of a macroprudential indicator and bankspecific characteristics ( MPk ,t * BSC i , k ,t 1 ):
Riski ,k ,t Riski ,k ,t 1 EDF _ NFk ,t MPk ,t MCk ,t BSCi ,k ,t 1 MPk ,t * BSCi ,k ,t 1 i k ,t i ,k ,t
(2)
Similarly, with the approach used by the bank lending channel literature, the relevant test is on the significance of . Broadly speaking, this approach assumes that after a monetary tightening episode (macroprudential tightening in our case), the ability to shield loan portfolios is different across banks. In particular, small and less strongly capitalised banks, which suffer from a high degree of informational frictions in financial markets, face a higher
9
cost in raising non-secured deposits and are forced to reduce their lending by more than other banks; illiquid banks have fewer options for shielding themselves from the effect of a prudential policy tightening on lending simply by drawing down cash and securities. Therefore, this literature does not analyse the macroeconomic impact of the “bank lending channel” on loans but asserts the existence of such a channel, based on the fact that different responses of lending supply among banks are detected. All bank-specific characteristics have been “demeaned” so that the coefficients and can be considered to be the effects on the average bank.
3.4 Endogeneity issues One possible limitation of the suggested empirical strategy is that, in principle, the situation of the banking sector could also have an impact on macroprudential policy decisions. In order to mitigate endogeneity problems, we use the dynamic Generalised Method of Moments (GMM) panel methodology to obtain consistent estimates of the relationship between macroprudential policy and bank risk. This methodology was first described by Holtz-Eakin et al (1988), and Arellano and Bond (1991), and further developed by Blundell and Bond (1998). The use of this methodology reduces any endogeneity bias that may affect the estimation of the regression parameters. It also takes into account the heterogeneity of the data caused by unobservable factors affecting individual banks. We use the instruments as defined by Blundell and Bond (1998). According to these authors, the exogenous variables, transformed in first differences, are instrumented by themselves, while the endogenous regressors (also transformed in first differences) are instrumented by their lags in levels.8 As a final precaution, we consider all bank-specific characteristics at t-1.
4. Results The main results are reported in Tables 4 to 7. The S-GMM estimator ensures efficiency and consistency, provided that the residuals are not subject to serial correlation of order two (AR(2) test), and that the instruments used are valid (Hansen test). Neither test (as reported at the bottom of each table) should fail to reject the null hypothesis.9 Table 4 presents the baseline regression results of specifications (1) and (2) using the MP_index. The table is split into two parts: the first two columns use the EDF as dependent 8
This approach has been applied to other areas of research in which the model was affected by possible endogeneity biases. For instance, Blundell and Bond (1998) use it to estimate a labour demand model while Beck et al (2000) apply it to investigate the relation between financial development and economic growth.
9
The consistency of the S-GMM estimator depends on the validity of the assumption that the error terms do not exhibit serial correlation and on the validity of the instruments. To address these issues, we use two specification tests suggested by Arellano and Bond (1991), and Blundell and Bond (1998). The first is a Hansen test of over-identifying restrictions, which tests the overall validity of the instruments by analysing the sample analogue of the moment conditions used in the estimation process. The second test examines the hypothesis that the error term
ikt
is not serially correlated. We test
whether the differenced error term is second-order serially correlated (by construction, the differenced error term is probably first-order serially correlated even if the original error term is not). Failure to reject the null hypotheses of both tests should give support to our models.
10
variable, while the last two columns use the Z-score. To make results comparable, we multiply the Z-score by -1. In this way larger values of both the EDF and Z-score indicate higher risk. The coefficients on the MP_index are negative and significant, indicating that a tightening (easing) of macroprudential policies reduces (increases) bank risk. All coefficients for bankspecific indicators are highly significant for the EDF and Z-score in our baseline model. The interaction terms between the MP_index and bank specific characteristics in column (2) and (4) indicate that the impact of macroprudential policies on bank risk is stronger for banks that are weakly capitalised, smaller, with low liquidity buffers and with a higher incidence of wholesale funding (fewer deposits). These results are in line with Gambacorta and Shin (2016): well capitalised banks are considered as less risky by the market and pay less – other things being equal – on their debt funding. Moreover, banks with a large proportion of deposits are considered safer because of the presence of deposit insurance. Figure 4 summarises the effects of macroprudential tools for banks with different levels of capital. The estimates roughly imply that a tightening of macroprudential tools leads to a decline in the expected default probability of around 0.7 percent for the average bank. The effect is higher for weakly capitalised banks (−0.9 percent) than for strongly capitalised ones (−0.4 percent), which have better access to markets for non-reservable liabilities. It is worth remembering that testing the null hypothesis that macroprudential policies effects are equal among banks with different capital ratios is identical to testing for the significance of the interaction between capital and the macroprudential policy indicator (see the coefficient on MP_indext*CAP t-1 in the second column of Table 4). Similar results are detected considering the Z-score as indicator of bank risk (see Figure 4 and the fourth column of Table 4). The analysis of the other control variables also provides interesting insights. The positive value of the lagged dependent variable indicates persistence in the adjustment process of risk. Changes in the EDF of the non-financial sector are positively linked to banks’ EDF and Zscores. This implies that the risks affecting financial firms are driven by broad movements in risk that are related to the overall behaviour of the economy (captured by non-financial sector risk). As indicated by the risk-taking channel, the monetary policy indicator (the difference between the real interest rate and the natural rate) is negatively correlated with bank risk. This means that a less restrictive monetary policy is associated with a higher level of bank risk. The state of the business cycle (growth rate of nominal GDP) is also negatively correlated with changes in bank risk-taking. However this effect is statistically significant only when the Zscore is used as a risk–taking measure. Table 5 presents the results of model (2) where the MP_index is divided in two separate indices, one for macroprudential tools aimed at dampening the credit cycle (MP_cyclical index for categories (c), (d) and (e) in Table 3) and another one for macroprudential tools whose main objective is to enhance the financial sector’s resilience (MP_resilience index for categories (a) and (b) in Table 3). We also find in this case the expected negative sign on the two macroprudential indices: a tightening (easing) of macroprudential policies reduces (increases) risk for the average bank (remember that all bank-specific characteristics are demeaned). The interaction of the two macroprudential indices with bank-specific characteristics confirms that the impact of macroprudential policies on bank risk is stronger for banks that are weakly capitalised, smaller, with low liquidity buffers and with a higher incidence of wholesale funding. Interestingly, the magnitude of the interaction terms is greater for macroprudential tools whose main objective 11
is to enhance the financial sector’s resilience. This is not surprising as these tools (capital and liquidity requirements) have a more direct impact on banks’ credit supply. In the first column of Table 6, we extend the analysis in two ways. First, we consider the possibility of asymmetric effects for a tightening and an easing of macroprudential policies. Second, we consider the five macroprudential categories described in Table 3. We find, in general, the expected signs. In the majority of cases, macroprudential tightening has a negative and significant impact on bank-risk, while easing has a positive effect. Similar results are obtained in the first column of Table 7 where we use changes in the Z-score as dependent variable rather than changes in the EDF. There are, however, cases (depending on the measure of bank risk used) in which some macroprudential tools do not produce significant effects on a bank’s risk. These cases have to be further investigated because the effect may not be homogenous among banks, ie affecting some banks with certain specific characteristics more than others. Another finding is that the effects are not always symmetric in magnitude for the average bank. However, the difference between the coefficients MP_easing and MP_tightening are in most cases not statistically significant. There is a slight tendency for asset class measures (such as changes in LTV or debt to income ratios) and, to some extent, currency tools to be more effective in an easing than in a tightening. On the contrary, reserve requirements seem more effective in a tightening but only when EDF is considered as a bank risk indicator. Moreover, in this case, the asymmetry needs further analysis by considering how banks with different characteristics react to changes in macroprudential tools. To this end, we extend the model by inserting interaction terms that are the products of macroprudential indicators and bank-specific characteristics (see equation (2)). As pointed out in section 3, this is similar to the approach taken by the bank lending channel literature, which identifies shifts in the supply of loans by considering a different reaction of banks to monetary policy shocks depending on their characteristics. In columns (II) to (V) of Table 6, we report estimation results for equation (3) for each bank-specific characteristic, one at a time. Table 7 does the same but considers the Z-score as a dependent variable. Three main results emerge. First, many interaction terms (17 out of 40 for EDF; 24 out of 40 for Z-score) are statistically significant, indicating that macroprudential policies have heterogeneous effects across banks. Table 6 results indicate that the significance and sign of the coefficients for the five groups of macroprudential tools in specifications (II) to (V) are consistent, in general, with those expected from theory. In particular, banks that are small, weakly capitalised and with a low proportion of deposit funding (more wholesale funding) react more strongly to macroprudential shocks. Given that small and less strongly capitalised banks suffer from a higher degree of informational friction in financial markets, and face higher costs in raising non-secured deposits, then macroprudential measures would be expected to have a larger impact on their risk-taking capacity. Liquidity does not seem to affect significantly a bank’s risk response to macroprudential changes, with the notable exception of a tightening of reserve requirements, against which liquid banks seem perfectly insulated. Third, controlling for bank characteristics, macroprudential tools are more effective in a tightening than in an easing episode. For instance, in Table 6 for EDF, 11 out of 20 interaction terms are significant at a conventional level for tightening measures, while it is 6 out of 20 for easing interactions. A similar pattern of interaction terms exists for the Z-score in Table 6 (14 12
out of 20 for tightening; 10 out of 20 for easing). Heterogeneity is particularly evident when considering banks with a different degree of leverage, in particular for the Z-score and deposit ratio for EDF results. The higher effectiveness of tightening measures when bank-specific interactions are considered is in line with Claessens et al (2013), Cerutti et al (2017) and McDonald (2015).
5. Robustness checks In this section, we perform a number of tests to check the robustness of our results to: i) the presence of possible heterogeneity in the effectiveness of macroprudential tools caused by different stages of economic and financial development across countries; ii) the effects of the GFC in the last part of the sample; iii) the effects of global macroeconomic and financial conditions; and iv) possible limits in our data coverage. Regarding possible difference in the effectiveness of macroprudential tools across jurisdictions, we divided the sample (3,177 banks and 20,870 observations) between advanced economies (2,286 banks and 15,144 observations) and EMEs (891 banks and 5,756 observations).10 This test is particularly relevant as the data for EMEs typically contain more gaps and are only available for a limited number of financial intermediaries. The results reported in Tables C1-C4 in Annex C indicate that in both groups of countries, macroprudential policies have a significant impact on banks’ risk-taking. Figure 5 reports the average effect of a macroprudential policy tightening, distinguishing those tools aimed at dampening the cycle (Cyclical) from those whose main objective is to enhance the financial sector’s resilience (Resilience). For example, on average, macroprudential tightening reduces the probability of a bank’s default by 0.35% (first histogram in the left-hand panel). The effect is higher in advanced economies (-0.47%) than in EMEs (-0.15%). Similar effects can be detected in terms of Z-scores. In addition, risk for banks that are small, less well capitalised and with a higher share of wholesale funding reacts more strongly to changes in macroprudential tools aggregated into an MP index (Tables C1 and C3). In both groups of country, the tools that primarily aim at enhancing resilience (MP resilience index) and those that focus above all on taming financial booms and busts (MP_cyclical index; see Tables C2 and C4) have an impact on bank risk. In the second robustness test, we limit our analysis to the pre-crisis period. Table C5 and C6 report the results for the baseline regressions estimated over the period 1990–2007. Even after losing one third of the observations, the results are qualitatively very similar. In the third test, we add to the equations a complete set of time dummies to capture changes in global macroeconomic and financial conditions. The results reported in Tables C7 and C8 remains very similar. The robustness of the results is also confirmed when we include in the specification a full set of country*time fixed effects (and drop the macroeconomic controls): sign and significance of the interaction terms between macroprudential index and bank-specific characteristics remain qualitatively very similar (see Table C9).
10
The distinction between advanced economies and EMEs is based on the 86th Annual report of the BIS, p. vii. Advanced economies are highlighted in italics in Annex A while the remaining economies, which are considered to be EMEs, are not.
13
The above results may also be influenced by differences in the intensity of bank supervision, unrelated to macroprudential policies, which could have an impact on the amount of risk undertaken (Beltratti and Stulz, 2012). In a fourth test, we therefore verify whether more permissive legislation on bank activities could have led financial intermediaries to take more risks. Following Karolyi and Taboada (2015), we construct a Regulatory Strength Index (RSI) using the logarithm of the sum of four indices that measures the quality of bank regulation from Barth et al (2013).11 As the index is available only for the period 1999–2012, the number of observations drops to 16,615. Tables C10 and C11 report the results including this indicator. We also report, for completeness, the coefficient of the crisis dummy k ,t (used in all specifications) which takes the value of 1 in those specific years during which countries experienced a banking crisis and zero elsewhere (Valencia and Laeven, 2012). Interestingly, the dummy that captures regulatory strength is negatively correlated with both measures of bank risk. At the same time, the dummy that captures the crisis picks up the effect of financial distress on banks. All other results remain practically unchanged. The use of the EDF measure as dependent variable for risk reduces the number of observations because this indicator is available only for a limited number of banks. As a final robustness check, we run the baseline regressions on a larger sample of financial intermediaries using only the Z-score. This allows us to increase the number of banks from 3,177 to 17,963, and the number of observations from 20,870 to 115,611. The results reported in Table C12 are qualitatively very similar.
6. Conclusions The global financial crisis highlighted the importance of financial stability, and hence the need for macroprudential policies to achieve that objective. Particularly during and after the crisis, many countries began to implement various macroprudential tools to deal with financial vulnerabilities and mitigate systemic risk. Recent theoretical and empirical literature has focused on various aspects of macroprudential policies, including the effectiveness of those policies and their implications for business and financial cycles. This paper fills an existing gap in the literature. In particular, while other studies focus on the impact of such policies on bank lending, our paper analyses their effectiveness on bank risk. We do this in a comprehensive way, exploiting the cross-sectional dimension of countries for a large panel of banks operating in 61 advanced economies and emerging market economies over the period ranging from 1990 to 2012. The paper presents three main results. First, it provides evidence suggesting that macroprudential tools are effective in modifying bank risk-taking. Second, the responses to
11
The indices and the question numbers (and their range) in Barth et al (2013) are as follows: I.IV: Overall Restrictions on Banking Activities (3-12); IV.III Capital Regulatory Index (0-10); V.I Official Supervisory Power (0-14); VII.VI Private Monitoring Index (0-12). The RSI could in principle take a value ranging from 3 (minimum regulation) to 48 (most stringent regulation). Barth et al (2013) provide surveys on bank regulation that were conducted in 1999, 2003, 2007 and 2011. Therefore, in order to not constraint our sample, we simply duplicate the missing years with the latest survey values. For 2000–2002, use the survey for 1999; for 2004–2006, the survey for 2003; for 2008–2010, the survey for 2007, and for 2012, the survey for 2011.
14
change in macroprudential tools differ among banks depending on their balance sheet characteristics. In particular, banks that are small, weakly capitalised and with a higher share of wholesale funding react more strongly to changes in these tools. Third, macroprudential policies seem more effective in a tightening than in an easing phase.
15
References Acharya, V and N Mora (2015): “A Crisis of Banks as Liquidity Providers”, The Journal of Finance, vol 70, pp 1–43. Adrian, T and H S Shin (2009): “Money, Liquidity and Monetary Policy”, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, vol 99, pp 600-605. Adrian, T and H S Shin (2010): “Liquidity and leverage”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, vol 19, pp 418–37. Adrian, T and H S Shin (2014): “Procyclical Leverage and Value-at-Risk”, The Review of Financial Studies,vol 27, n 2, pp 373-403. Altman, E I, G Marco and F Varetto (1994): “Corporate distress diagnosis: Comparisons using linear discriminant analysis and neural networks (the Italian experience)”, Journal of Banking and Finance, vol 18, pp. 505-529. Altunbas, Y, L Gambacorta and D Marques-Ibanez (2014): “Does monetary policy affect bank risk?”, International Journal of Central Banking, vol 10, n 1, pp 95–135. Arellano, M and S Bond (1991): “Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations”, Review of Economic Studies, vol 58, n 2, pp 277–297. Barth, J R, G J Caprio and R Levine (2013): “Bank Regulation and Supervision in 180 Countries from 1999 to 2011”, NBER Working Paper, n 18733. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2010): “Basel III: A global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems”, Basel, Bank for International Settlements. Basten, C and C Koch (2015): “Higher bank capital requirements and mortgage pricing: Evidence from the countercyclical capital buffer”, BIS Working Papers, n 511. Beck, T, R Levine and N Loayza (2000): “Finance and the sources of growth”, Journal of Financial Economics, Elsevier, vol. 58, n 1, pp 261-300. Beltratti, A, and R M Stulz (2012): “The Credit Crisis around the Globe: Why Did Some Banks Perform Better?”, Journal of Financial Economics, vol 105, n 1, pp 1–17. Berlin M and L J Mester, (1999): “Deposits and Relationship Lending”, Review of Financial Studies, vol 12, n 3, pp 579-607. Bernanke, B, M Gertler and S Gilchrist (1996): “The Financial Accelerator and the Flight to Quality”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 78, n 1, pp 1-15. Blundell, R and S Bond (1998): “Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models”, Journal of Econometrics, vol 87, n 2, pp 115–143. Bollerslev, T, R Y Chou and K F Kroner (1992): “ARCH modelling in finance: a review of the theory and empirical evidence”, Journal of Econometrics, vol 52, pp 5-59. Borio, C (2011): “Implementing a macroprudential framework: blending boldness and realism”, Capitalism and Society, vol 6, n 1. Borio, C (2014): "Monetary policy and financial stability: what role in prevention and recovery?”, Capitalism and Society, vol 9, n 2. Borio, C and H Zhu (2014): "Capital regulation, risk-taking and monetary policy: A missing link in the transmission mechanism?", Journal of Financial Stability, vol 8, n 4, pp 236–251.
16
Borio, C and I Shim (2007): “What can (macro-) prudential policy do to support monetary policy?”, BIS Working Papers, n 242. Cerutti, E, S Claessens and L Laeven (2017): “The use and effectiveness of macroprudential policies: New evidence”, Journal of Financial Stability, vol 28, pp 203-224. Claessens, S (2015): “An overview of macroprudential policy tools", Annual Review of Financial Economics, vol 7, n 1, pp 397-422. Claessens, S, S R Ghosh, and R Mihet (2013): “Macro-Prudential Policies to Mitigate Financial System Vulnerabilities”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 2013, vol 39, pp 153-185. Committee on the Global Financial System (2012): “Operationalising the selection and application of macroprudential instruments”, CGFS Papers, n 48, December. Crowe, C, G Dell’Ariccia, D Igan and P Rabanal (2011): “How to deal with real estate booms: lessons from country experiences”, IMF Working Paper, n 91. Danielsson, J, H S Shin and J P Zigrand (2004): “The impact of risk regulation on price dynamics”, Journal of Banking and Finance, vol 28, pp 1069–87. Dell'Ariccia, G, L Laeven and R Marquez (2010): “Monetary Policy, Leverage, and Bank Risk-Taking”, IMF Working Paper, n 276. Demirgüç-Kunt, A, E Detragiache and O Merrouche (2013): “Bank Capital: Lessons from the Financial Crisis”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol 45, n 6, pp 1147–1164. Diamond D W and R G Rajan (2012): "Illiquid Banks, Financial Stability, and Interest Rate Policy", Journal of Political Economy, vol 120, n 3, pp 552 – 591. Drehmann, M and L Gambacorta (2012): “The Effects of Countercyclical Capital Buffers on Bank Lending”, Applied Economic Letters, vol 19, n 7, pp 603-608. Farhi, E and J Tirole (2012): “Collective Moral Hazard, Maturity Mismatch and Systemic Bailouts”, American Economic Review, vol 102, n 1, pp 60-93. Financial Stability Board, International Monetary Fund, and Bank for International Settlements (FSB/IMF/BIS) (2009): Guidance to Assess the Systemic Importance of Financial Institutions, Markets and Instruments: Initial Considerations”, report to the G-20 finance ministers and central bank governors (Basel). Gambacorta, L (2005): “Inside the bank lending channel”, European Economic Review, vol 49, pp 17371759. Gambacorta, L (2009): "Monetary policy and the risk-taking channel”, BIS Quarterly Review, Bank for International Settlements, December. Gambacorta, L and H S Shin (2016): “Why bank capital matters for monetary policy”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, forthcoming. Hilbers, P, I Otker-Robe, C Pazarbasioglu and G Johnsen (2005): “Assessing and managing rapid credit growth and the role of supervisory and prudential policies”, IMF Working Paper, n 151. Holtz-Eakin, D, W Newey and H S Rosen (1988): “Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data”, Econometrica, vol 56, n 6, pp 1371–1395. Igan, D and H Kang (2011): “Do Loan-to-Value and Debt-to-Income Limits Work? Evidence from Korea”, IMF Working Paper, n 297. International Monetary Fund (2011): “Macroprudential Policy: An Organizing Framework”, Background Paper.
17
International Monetary Fund (2013): “The Interaction of Monetary and Macroprudential Policies”, IMF Policy Paper. Karolyi, A and A G Taboada (2015): “Regulatory Arbitrage and Cross-Border Bank Acquisitions”, The Journal of Finance, vol 70, n 6, pp 2395-2451. Kashyap, A K and J C Stein (2000): “What Do a Million Observations on Banks Say About the Transmission of Monetary Policy”, American Economic Review, vol 90, n 3, pp 407-428. Kishan, R P and T P Opiela (2000): “Bank Size, Bank Capital, and the Bank Lending Channel”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol 32 , n 1, pp 121-141. Kuttner, K N and I Shim (2016): “Can non-interest rate policies stabilise housing markets? Evidence from a panel of 57 economies”, Journal of Financial Stability, vol 26, pp 31–44. Laeven, L and R Levine (2009): “Bank governance, regulation and risk taking”, Journal of Financial Economics, vol 93, n 2, pp. 259-275. Lim, C H, F Columba, A Costa, P Kongsamut, A Otani, M Saiyid, T Wezel, and X Wu (2011): “Macroprudential Policy: What Instruments and How to Use Them? Lessons from Country Experiences,” IMF Working Paper, n 238. Lim, C H, I Krznar, F Lipinsky, A Otani, and X Wu (2013): “The Macroprudential Framework: Policy Responsiveness and Institutional Arrangements”, IMF Working Paper, n 166. McDonald, C (2015): “When is macroprudential policy effective?”, BIS Working Papers n 496. Merton, R C (1974): "On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates," Journal of Finance, American Finance Association, vol 29, n 2, pp 449-70. Pagan, A and W Schwert (1990): “Alternative models for conditional stock volatility”, Journal of Econometrics, vol 45, pp 267–90. Rajan, R (2005): “Has financial development made the world riskier?”, NBER Working Paper, n 11728. Shim, I, B Bogdanova, J Shek and A Subelyte (2013): “Database for policy actions on housing markets”, BIS Quarterly Review, September, pp. 83–95. Tovar, C, M Garcia-Escribano and M V Martin (2012): “Credit growth and the effectiveness of reserve requirements and other macroprudential instruments in Latin America”, IMF Working Paper, n 142. Valencia F and L Laeven (2012): "Systemic Banking Crises Database: An Update", IMF Working Papers, n 163.
18
Figure 1: Macroprudential measures over time1 Number of macroprudential policy actions 100
75
50
25
0 1992
1990
1994
Advanced economies
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
Emerging market economies
The sample covers 1,047 macroprudential policy actions adopted in 64 countries (29 advanced and 35 emerging market economies). The database has been constructed using information in Kuttner and Shim (2016) and Lim et al (2013). Sources: IMF, BIS. 1
Figure 2: Cross-sectional dispersion of bank risk measures 0.7
5
Coefficient of Variation - EDF
0.6 4 0.5
3.5 3
0.4
2.5 0.3
2 1.5
0.2
1 0.1
Coefficient of Variation - log Z-Score
4.5
0.5 0 1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
EDF
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
0 2014
Ln Z-Score
Source: Authors’ calculations. Note: The coefficient of variation is given by the ratio of the standard error to the mean. The series show the coefficient of variation of banks’ expected default frequency (left hand scale) and the Z-score (right hand scale) in each year.
19
Figure 3: Use of macroprudential instruments. Different kinds of policies In percent Type of instrument Currency
Type of measure
Capital based
4% 17% 6% 53%
Reserve requirement
Liquidity based
40% 60%
20%
Asset side
Resilience Cyclical
Loosening measures Tightening measures
Note: Resilience macroprudential tools include: a) capital based instruments (countercyclical capital requirements, leverage restrictions, general or dynamic provisioning) and b) the establishment of liquidity requirements. Cyclical macroprudential tools consider: c) asset side instruments (credit growth limits, maximum debt service-to-income ratio, limits to banks’ exposures to the housing sector as maximum loan to value ratio); d) changes in reserve requirements; e) currency instruments (variations in limits on foreign currency exchange mismatches and net open positions). Source: IMF, BIS, authors’ calculations.
Figure 4: Effect of a macroprudential tool tightening: well vs low capitalized banks EDF
Z-score
0.00
0.00
–0.25
–0.02
–0.50
–0.04
–0.75
–0.06
–1.00
–0.08 Average
High capitalised Low capitalised
Note: The graph reports the effect on bank risk of a tightening in
macroprudential tool. The left part indicates the effects on banks’ expected default frequency (left-hand axis), the right part the effects on the Z-score (right-hand axis).
Source: Authors’ calculations
20
Figure 5: Average impact of a macroprudential tightening on bank risk: Advanced vs emerging market economies Expected default frequency (left hand side) and Z-score (right hand side) All countries EDF
Advanced economies
Z-score
EDF
Emerging market economies
Z-score
EDF
Z-score
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
–0.15
–0.03
–0.15
–0.03
–0.15
–0.03
–0.30
–0.06
–0.30
–0.06
–0.30
–0.06
–0.45
–0.09
–0.45
–0.09
–0.45
–0.09
–0.12
–0.60
–0.12
–0.60
–0.60 All
Cyclical Resilience
All
Cyclical Resilience
–0.12 All
Cyclical Resilience
Note: The Expected default frequency (EDF) represents the probability that a bank will default within one year. The EDF is a well-known, forward-looking indicator of risk, computed by Moody’s KMV, which builds on Merton’s model to price corporate bond debt (Merton, 1974). The EDF value, expressed as a percentage, is calculated by combining banks’ financial statements with stock market information and Moody’s proprietary default database. The Z-score is an alternative measure for risk and it can be summarized as Z=(k+ROA)/σROA, where k is equity capital as percent of assets, ROA is average after-tax return as percent on assets, and σROA is standard deviation of the after-tax return on assets, as a proxy for return volatility. The Z-score measures the number of standard deviations a return realization has to fall in order to deplete equity, under the assumption of normality of banks’ returns. A higher Z-score corresponds to a lower upper bound of insolvency risk, therefore it implies a lower probability of insolvency risk. To compare the signs of the coefficients in the regressions, we have therefore multiplied the Z-score by -1. Source: Authors’ calculations.
21
Table 1: Summary statistics of the variables used in the regressions (1990-2012)1 Variables
Number of observations
Mean
Median
Std. Dev
Min
Max
1st 3rd quartile quartile
Sources
EDF
20,870
0.116
-0.003
2.094
-32.275
29.65
-0.111
0.157
Moody’s KMV
Z-score
20,870
-2.685
-2.847
-1.256
-5.298
-4.605
-3.467
-2.078
Authors’ calc.
EDF_NFS
20,870
-0.069
-0.150
1.546
-6.448
8.236
-1.022
0.771
Moody’s KMV
DIFF
20,870
-0.012
-0.009
0.025
-0.220
0.235
-0.023
0.001
IMF/WB/OECD
GDP
20,870
2.760
2.720
2.967
-13.130
15.060
1.450
4.350
IMF/WB/OECD
DEP
20,870
0.000
0.067
1.180
-0.802
0.966
-0.076
0.136
BankScope
SIZE
20,870
0.000
-0.137
2.192
-16.031
7.932
-1.443
1.365
BankScope
CAP
20,870
0.000
-0.048
0.176
-0.141
0.879
-0.075
-0.015
BankScope
LIQ
20,870
0.000
-0.053
0.205
-0.267
0.783
-0.150
0.083
BankScope See Annex B
MP index cum
20,870
0.100
0
0.589
-3
3
0
0
MP cyclical
20,870
0.001
0
0.440
-1
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP resilience
20,870
0.037
0
0.298
-1
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP_capital_easing
20,870
0.018
0
0.132
0
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP_liquidity_easing
20,870
0.011
0
0.106
0
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP_assets_easing
20,870
0.025
0
0.155
0
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP_currency_easing
20,870
0.005
0
0.069
0
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP_reserve_easing
20,870
0.071
0
0.257
0
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP_capital_tightening
20,870
0.066
0
0.248
0
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP_liquidity_tightening
20,870
0.012
0
0.109
0
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP_assets_tightening
20,870
0.08
0
0.271
0
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP_currency_tightening
20,870
0.012
0
0.110
0
1
0
0
See Annex B
MP_reserve_tightening
20,870
0.060
0
0.238
0
1
0
0
See Annex B
Regulatory strength
16,615
30.39
31
5.718
11
45
28
34
Banking crisis
20,870
0.040
0
0.195
0
1
0
0
Barth et al (2013) Valencia and Laeven (2012)
Note: (1) Bank specific indicators are in mean deviation form. where: EDF=change in the EDF at the bank level (1 year ahead) Z-score = indicator of the probability of default which is computed on the base of balance sheet variables EDF_NFS = EDF change for the non-financial sector at the country level (1 year ahead) DIFF = real money market interest rate minus natural rate GDP = changes in nominal GDP DEP = deposit-to-total liability ratio *100 SIZE = log of total assets (USD millions) CAP = capital-to-total asset ratio *100 LIQ= cash and securities-to- total asset ratio*100 MP index = aggregate macroprudential index MP cyclical=index for macroprudential policies that aim at dampening cycle MP resilience= index for macroprudential policies that aim at increasing system resilience MP_capital = capital based macroprudential tool MP_liquidity = liquidity based macroprudential tool MP_asset = asset side based macroprudential tool MP_currency = currency requirement macroprudential tool MP_reserve = reserve based macroprudential tool (reserve requirement) Regulatory strength = index for overall banking regulation quality Bank crisis = dummy equal to 1 if the country where the bank is headquartered is in a banking crisis
22
Table 2: Balance sheet characteristics and bank risk profile (1) Lending
Size
Liquidity
Capitalization
Deposits
Cost to income ratio
ROA
ROA variability (2)
EDF / Z-Score
(annual growth rate)
(USD mill.)
(% total assets)
(% total assets)
(% total assets)
(%)
(%)
(coefficient of variation)
(%)
Panel A: Distribution by bank risk (one-year ahead EDF) A1: Full Sample High-risk banks Low-risk banks
5.085 14.268
15.551 16.251
15.523 17.923
13.460 16.995
70.351 67.256
73.425 58.835
0.312 2.588
83.506 41.575
7.356 0.070
A2: Advanced Economies High-risk banks Low-risk banks
1.519 13.820
15.863 16.279
12.800 17.510
11.717 15.616
70.952 67.210
74.489 59.631
-0.086 2.330
76.408 41.144
8.318 0.060
A3: Emerging Economies High-risk banks Low-risk banks
11.525 17.491
14.990 16.053
20.425 20.758
16.602 26.476
69.253 67.606
71.523 53.114
1.030 4.365
96.057 44.614
5.621 0.138
Panel A: Distribution by bank risk (Z-Score) A1: Full Sample High-risk banks Low-risk banks
6.733 9.310
15.965 15.749
18.597 11.167
9.316 12.339
73.891 74.793
84.518 58.546
-0.138 1.045
84.627 15.440
0.227 4.390
A2: Advanced Economies High-risk banks Low-risk banks
4.226 8.717
16.173 15.703
18.452 9.411
8.404 11.510
73.176 74.933
83.946 59.678
0.071 0.978
77.466 14.071
0.192 4.396
A3: Emerging Economies High-risk banks 12.847 15.455 18.952 11.542 75.651 85.906 -0.646 102.450 Low-risk banks 12.680 16.003 20.961 16.963 73.992 51.789 1.422 25.356 Note: (1) A low-risk bank has an average ratio of the EDF (Z-score) in the first decile of the distribution by bank risk; a high-risk bank an average EDF (Z-score) in the last decile. (2) Coefficient of variation of the Return on Assets (ROA) is calculated for the 4 quarters ahead.
23
0.311 4.354
Table 3: Use of macroprudential instruments Total measures
Type of instrument a. Capital based instruments Capital requirement/Risk weights (RW) Provisioning requirement (Prov)
Frequency of use (percent)
Tightening measures
Loosening measures
(I)
(II)
(III)
(IV)
178
17.0
148
30
127
12.1
108
19
51
4.9
40
11
64
6.1
26
38
b. Liquidity based instruments Liquidity requirements (Liq) c. Asset side instruments
207
19.8
146
61
Credit growth limits (Credit)
51
4.9
31
20
Maximum debt-service-to-income ratio and other lending criteria (DSTI)
36
3.4
31
5
Limits on banks’ exposure to the housing sector
11
1.1
7
4
Maximum loan-to-value ratio and loan prohibition (LTV)
109
10.4
77
32
d. Reserve requirement (RR)
558
53.3
278
280
e. Currency instruments Net open position (NOP)
40
3.8
29
11
26
2.5
17
9
14
1.3
12
2
Foreign currency lending limits (FCL)
Total 1,047 100 627 420 Notes: The table shows the number of policy actions taken by the countries in the sample. Frequency of use in column (II) indicates the share of each policy action among the total in column (I).
24
Table 4: Baseline regression with aggregate macroprudential index
Dependent variablet-1
EDF_NFSt
Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) (II)
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score
Coeff
Coeff
0.221
Std err ***
0.003
Coeff
Std err
0.216
(III)
(IV) Std err
***
0.006
0.894
***
0.020
Coeff
Std err
0.931
***
0.125
0.411
***
0.067
0.395
***
0.060
0.019
***
0.005
0.018
***
0.005
DIFFt
-0.012
**
0.006
-0.020
**
0.009
-0.01
**
0.005
-0.003
**
0.001
GDPt
-0.839
0.703
-0.533
0.671
-0.665
***
0.065
-0.423
***
0.113
SIZEt-1
-0.01
***
0.003
-0.071
**
0.036
-0.021
***
0.003
-0.014
*
0.008
LIQt-1
-0.118
***
0.015
-0.090
*
0.051
-0.043
*
0.024
-0.075
**
0.036
CAPt-1
-0.158
***
0.027
-1.027
**
0.468
-0.86
***
0.048
-0.517
**
0.244
DEPt-1
-0.063
**
0.031
-0.627
***
0.216
-0.973
***
0.030
-0.678
***
0.240
MP_indext
-0.655
***
0.066
-0.670
***
0.237
-0.007
**
0.003
-0.012
*
0.007
MP_indext*CAP t-1
3.189
***
0.357
0.317
***
0.032
MP_indext*SIZE t-1
0.491
***
0.057
0.007
*
0.004
MP_indext*LIQ t-1
0.201
*
0.116
-0.038
0.194
*
0.117
MP_indext*DEP t-1 Sample period
0.247
0.074 ***
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
Observations
20,870
20,870
20,870
20,870
Serial correlation test1
0.110
0.140
0.066
0.127
Hansen test2
0.560
0.640
0.730
0.760
0.030
Notes: The database is composed of 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank-year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
25
Table 5: Cyclical vs Resilience macroprudential tools Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) Coeff
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (II)
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.089
**
0.043
0.890
***
0.067
EDF_NFSt
0.090
0.032
***
0.005
0.614
***
DIFFt
-0.041
**
GDPt
-1.517
SIZEt-1
-0.053
LIQt-1
-0.278
CAPt-1
-1.711
DEPt-1 MP_Cyclical indext MP_Resilience_indext
0.019
-0.018
***
0.004
2.442
-0.768
***
0.261
*
0.027
-0.012
**
0.005
***
0.015
-0.158
***
0.060
***
0.507
-0.425
***
0.112
-1.299
***
0.192
-0.547
***
0.100
-0.473
**
0.194
-0.037
*
0.020
-0.158
***
0.042
-0.066
***
0.001
MP_Cyclical indext * CAPt-1
1.510
***
0.434
0.568
***
0.145
MP_Cyclical indext * SIZEt-1
0.125
*
0.067
0.009
*
0.005
MP_Cyclical indext * LIQt-1
0.551
***
0.010
0.162
***
0.040
MP_Cyclical indext * DEPt-1
0.545
**
0.237
0.117
*
0.069
MP_ Resilience indext * CAPt-1
2.056
**
0.913
0.621
***
0.183
MP_ Resilience indext * SIZEt-1
0.088
**
0.035
0.031
***
0.006
MP_ Resilience indext * LIQt-1
0.304
*
0.158
0.104
*
0.058
MP_ Resilience indext * DEPt-1
1.501
**
0.737
0.101
***
0.020
Sample period Observations Serial correlation test
1990-2012
1990-2012
20,870
20,870
0.077
0.275
1
Hansen test2
0.358 0.180 Notes: The database is composed of 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank-year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
26
Table 6: Bank-specific characteristics: Impact on EDF Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon
Baseline model (I)
Interactions with: bank size (II)
Interactions with: liquidity ratio (III)
Interactions with: leverage ratio (IV)
Interactions with: deposit ratio (V)
Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.265***
0.027
0.235***
0.010
0.207***
0.012
0.234***
0.050
0.248***
0.001
EDF_NFSt
0.412***
0.028
0.216***
0.027
0.247***
0.026
0.236***
0.035
0.259***
0.048
DIFFt
-0.044***
0.004
-0.027**
0.012
-0.022*
0.012
-0.067***
0.012
-0.062***
0.007
GDPt
-0.060
1.503
-2.607**
1.140
-2.552**
1.190
-3.156***
0.396
-1.936**
0.820
SIZEt-1
-0.020***
0.003
-0.020
0.025
LIQt-1
-0.272***
0.022
-0.840*
0.505
CAPt-1
-0.704***
0.273
-0.258***
0.071
DEPt-1
-0.458***
0.054
-1.022***
0.182
MP_capital_easingt
0.187***
0.024
0.105
0.261
0.331**
0.162
0.313***
0.106
0.473***
0.126
MP_liquidity_easingt
0.153
0.168
0.552
0.339
0.346
0.246
0.046
0.098
0.004
0.003
MP_assets_easingt
0.658***
0.297
0.657***
0.207
0.289**
0.144
0.437***
0.038
3.073***
0.351
MP_currency_easingt
0.431***
0.056
1.033***
0.440
1.580***
0.358
1.970***
0.323
2.408***
0.529
0.898**
0.362
1.713***
0.422
1.372***
0.256
1.185***
0.289
1.683***
0.163
MP_capital_tighteningt
-0.475
0.302
-1.023*
0.531
-0.200
0.306
-0.553***
0.213
-0.689***
0.265
MP_liquidity_tighteningt
-0.213
0.300
-0.134
0.264
-0.043
0.200
-0.140
0.106
-0.034
0.192
MP_assets_tighteningt
-0.149***
0.013
-0.634***
0.194
-0.277
0.124
-0.275***
0.051
-0.113
0.246
MP_currency_tighteningt
-0.592***
0.140
-0.817***
0.266
-0.785***
0.216
-0.835***
0.079
-1.462***
0.441
MP_reserve_tighteningt
-1.487***
0.379
-1.828***
0.454
-1.143***
0.286
-1.955***
0.275
-1.806***
0.102
MP_capital_easingt*Xt-1
-0.034
0.098
0.406
1.162
-1.941
1.882
-0.067
0.348
MP_liquidity_easingt*Xt-1
0.146
0.158
-1.448
1.676
-0.430*
0.241
-0.632
0.656
MP_reserve_easingt
MP_assets_easingt*Xt-1
-0.155**
0.071
2.936
7.861
-0.601***
0.100
-6.927
4.596
MP_currency_easingt*Xt-1
-0.881***
0.285
-0.607
1.863
-2.131***
0.365
-2.609
2.282
MP_reserve_easingt*Xt-1
-0.499***
0.107
-0.331
0.934
-0.257
0.721
-0.270
0.280
0.258*
0.132
-0.143
0.868
0.378***
0.130
0.285
0.872
MP_capital_tighteningt*Xt-1 MP_liquidity_tighteningt*Xt-1
0.076
0.127
0.112
1.365
-0.648
0.940
1.062***
0.198
MP_assets_tighteningt*Xt-1
0.062
0.048
-0.760
0.915
0.553***
0.192
0.583
0.498
MP_currency_tighteningt*Xt-1
0.164*
0.098
-1.132
2.333
0.665***
0.244
4.978***
1.867
0.426***
0.126
1.854*
1.034
1.662***
0.254
1.646***
0.350
MP_reserve_tighteningt*Xt-1 Sample period Observations Serial correlation test Hansen test
2
1
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
20,870
20,870
20,870
20,870
20,870
0.120
0.408
0.342
0.534
0.304
0.709
0.690
0.780
0.423
0.760
Notes: The database is composed of 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bankyear level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
27
Table 7: Bank-specific characteristics: Impact on Z-score Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score
Baseline model (I)
Interactions with: bank size (II)
Interactions with: liquidity ratio (III)
Interactions with: leverage ratio (IV)
Interactions with: deposit ratio (V)
Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.612***
0.009
0.655***
0.007
0.617***
0.030
0.626***
0.001
0.702***
0.039
EDF_NFSt
0.035***
0.004
0.020***
0.002
0.061***
0.007
0.032***
0.002
0.036***
0.008
DIFFt
-0.022***
0.003
-0.018***
0.001
-0.018***
0.004
-0.022***
0.005
-0.010***
0.002
GDPt
-2.014***
0.196
-1.479***
0.103
-1.614***
0.372
-1.258***
0.234
-1.046***
0.108
SIZEt-1
-0.023**
0.011
-0.018***
0.001
LIQt-1
-0.059
0.082
0.189
0.153
CAPt-1
-0.684***
0.203
-0.520***
0.164
DEPt-1
-0.466***
0.090
-0.379***
0.027
MP_capital_easingt
0.037
0.041
0.225***
0.007
0.072*
0.042
-0.011
0.185
0.064***
0.013
MP_liquidity_easingt
0.088
0.058
0.055***
0.005
-0.031
0.118
-0.034
0.029
-0.016
0.042
MP_assets_easingt
0.156***
0.059
0.013
0.032
-0.022
0.036
0.006
0.038
0.039*
0.022
MP_currency_easingt
0.392***
0.088
0.065
0.101
0.347***
0.077
0.166**
0.071
0.401***
0.039
MP_reserve_easingt
0.087**
0.044
0.313***
0.013
-0.045
0.043
0.015
0.026
0.014
0.031
MP_capital_tighteningt
-0.040
0.040
-0.004
0.039
-0.026
0.030
0.018
0.013
-0.016
0.018
MP_liquidity_tighteningt
-0.188***
0.054
-0.218***
0.028
-0.369***
0.057
-0.107***
0.023
-0.167***
0.015
MP_assets_tighteningt
-0.154**
0.025
-0.014
0.009
-0.017
0.035
-0.040
0.058
-0.021**
0.009
MP_currency_tighteningt
-0.279***
0.053
-0.120***
0.025
-0.181***
0.044
-0.078***
0.030
-0.460***
0.014
MP_reserve_tighteningt
-0.074**
0.033
-0.163***
0.012
-0.045*
0.028
-0.090***
0.007
-0.053***
0.019
MP_capital_easingt*Xt-1
-0.103***
0.028
0.668
0.413
-1.123
1.703
-0.546***
0.037
MP_liquidity_easingt*Xt-1
-0.059***
0.005
-0.147
0.675
0.056
0.160
-0.443***
0.033
-0.002
0.012
-0.440*
0.249
-0.748
0.584
-1.244***
0.114
MP_assets_easingt*Xt-1 MP_currency_easingt*Xt-1
-0.062***
0.012
-0.397
0.481
-1.178***
0.236
0.545
1.431
MP_reserve_easingt*Xt-1
-0.080***
0.004
-0.494*
0.272
0.245
0.159
0.547
0.568
MP_capital_tighteningt*Xt-1
0.000
0.012
1.351***
0.384
0.869***
0.108
0.444***
0.099
MP_liquidity_tighteningt*Xt-1
0.045***
0.001
0.315
0.369
0.306***
0.097
-0.086
0.073
MP_assets_tighteningt*Xt-1
-0.016*
0.009
-0.512
0.348
0.307***
0.070
-0.087
0.096
MP_currency_tighteningt*Xt-1
-0.007
0.027
1.126***
0.347
1.718***
0.430
0.390***
0.104
0.040***
0.006
0.682**
0.332
1.567***
0.117
1.131***
0.044
MP_reserve_tighteningt*Xt-1 Sample period Observations Serial correlation test Hansen test
2
1
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
20,870
20,870
20,870
20,870
20,870
0.242
0.104
0.270
0.119
0.101
0.699
0.690
0.590
0.760
0.600
Notes: Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank-year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
28
Annex A: Descriptive statistics by country (mean values: 1990-2012) Nominal GDP
Money market rate
Bank size, total assets
Loan growth
Capital
Liquidity
Deposits
EDF (banks)
Z-score (1)
EDF non financial firms (2)
Banking crisis
Number of banks (3)
Weight inside sample (4)
(Annual growth rate)
(Annual interest rate)
(log(USD millions))
(Annual growth rate)
(% of total assets)
(% of total assets)
(% of total assets)
(1 year ahead)
(%)
(Average quarterly changes)
(number of crisis)
(Final dataset)
(%)
AE
2.70
5.05
15.72
13.10
21.40
18.80
67.20
0.84
2.95
2.22
0.00
19
0.60
AR
4.40
11.25
15.47
8.60
14.00
31.80
71.40
1.84
1.85
5.28
0.08
8
0.25
Country
AT
2.00
2.43
15.91
5.90
13.40
19.40
62.20
0.90
3.12
2.50
0.09
31
0.98
AU
3.20
5.19
16.54
12.00
8.60
8.90
73.10
0.80
3.38
3.86
0.00
27
0.85
BE
1.70
2.77
17.65
5.30
14.70
17.90
68.70
1.09
2.30
2.35
0.05
21
0.66
BH
5.20
2.51
15.22
3.10
19.30
21.50
61.00
1.86
2.51
0.20
0.00
15
0.47
BR
3.30
22.88
15.84
17.20
14.70
25.00
64.00
2.58
2.54
8.27
0.02
34
1.07
CA
2.00
2.93
16.81
11.40
12.10
14.80
70.90
0.86
3.18
5.60
0.00
21
0.66
CH
1.80
1.65
15.07
7.60
28.60
26.90
58.20
0.91
2.78
1.54
0.06
49
1.54
CL
4.50
5.02
15.87
16.10
10.50
15.20
71.90
0.37
3.26
2.56
0.00
13
0.41
CN
10.20
2.87
18.92
23.00
7.80
24.80
87.20
0.68
3.03
1.55
0.00
26
0.82
CO
4.30
9.04
15.20
17.00
18.40
17.80
72.30
1.31
3.04
2.46
0.02
13
0.41
CZ
2.50
4.40
15.97
10.10
8.20
17.80
82.50
0.51
2.44
3.51
0.00
10
0.31
DE
1.50
3.00
15.97
4.70
13.60
23.00
56.60
2.39
2.53
3.71
0.07
88
2.77
DK
1.20
2.85
13.85
9.20
11.90
18.60
77.40
1.05
2.47
2.64
0.07
72
2.27
EG
4.60
6.94
14.82
9.20
13.50
26.70
81.60
1.78
2.28
1.48
0.00
15
0.47
ES
2.10
3.44
16.92
9.00
7.90
16.70
76.90
0.68
3.17
1.94
0.08
35
1.10
FI
2.50
3.43
15.24
8.30
28.40
14.20
62.40
0.39
2.53
1.69
0.00
22
0.69
FR
1.50
3.12
15.93
3.00
8.80
13.70
71.50
0.83
1.25
3.46
0.06
127
4.00
GB
2.50
4.22
15.95
6.80
28.30
28.90
53.30
0.97
2.52
3.39
0.07
132
4.15
(continues on the next pages)
29
(Annex A - continued) GR
1.10
4.60
16.47
15.30
9.50
HK
4.20
2.13
HU
1.70
7.35
ID
5.10
IE
4.90
19.90
82.20
2.69
1.45
15.45
9.20
22.50
26.00
71.50
0.93
3.20
15.51
15.00
8.20
16.70
61.70
1.71
2.37
10.05
14.63
21.30
12.00
23.50
80.40
2.91
2.18
3.24
17.68
12.70
4.80
21.40
73.50
1.28
2.05
5.76
0.08
25
0.79
3.69
0.00
30
0.94
4.60
0.08
9
0.28
6.32
0.03
50
1.57
2.66
0.05
14
0.44
IL
4.00
4.79
16.93
8.00
8.90
17.00
76.30
2.07
3.07
3.56
0.00
10
0.31
IN
7.40
10.17
16.05
18.90
11.30
16.00
75.50
1.85
2.93
6.11
0.00
61
1.92
IS
4.20
11.72
16.39
38.60
13.40
19.10
38.70
0.42
1.99
1.58
0.21
9
0.28
IT
0.70
3.72
16.45
10.30
11.50
23.80
62.80
0.66
2.91
2.32
0.06
104
3.27
JO
5.40
3.75
15.00
10.80
13.10
21.10
80.60
0.57
2.65
1.38
0.00
17
0.54
JP
0.80
0.44
16.98
1.80
9.70
12.70
83.70
1.19
2.71
2.80
0.03
200
6.30
KR
4.40
5.07
15.98
7.80
18.50
22.60
63.30
2.16
2.21
4.28
0.03
68
2.14
KW
3.80
2.53
14.69
4.60
34.80
20.40
57.40
1.63
1.73
1.61
0.00
18
0.57
LK
5.80
14.71
13.23
15.50
15.40
15.70
59.90
1.18
3.18
2.11
0.00
14
0.44
LU
3.60
2.82
15.30
10.30
26.50
28.40
66.00
1.18
2.56
2.22
0.03
9
0.28
MA
4.50
3.27
15.92
14.50
8.80
23.50
84.30
0.17
3.70
0.45
0.00
12
0.38
MX
2.70
11.73
15.58
17.60
19.80
29.60
64.90
1.71
1.94
3.34
0.01
12
0.38
MY
5.10
3.26
14.78
11.90
37.00
18.40
62.90
1.03
2.93
3.68
0.01
30
0.94
NL
1.80
2.77
16.90
11.80
23.40
26.00
60.30
1.44
2.71
2.27
0.07
24
0.76
NO
1.80
4.74
14.85
9.00
9.80
7.70
62.80
1.57
3.12
3.96
0.00
52
1.64
NZ
2.80
5.35
16.04
8.10
5.50
7.40
81.50
4.71
3.01
3.12
0.00
5
0.16
PA
5.50
4.81
12.61
17.70
9.30
17.50
80.60
1.27
3.81
0.65
0.00
1
0.03
PE
5.50
5.91
14.97
14.80
10.20
22.10
81.80
2.09
2.71
5.54
0.00
13
0.41
PH
4.70
7.19
14.50
9.70
16.30
27.10
75.40
1.51
3.34
6.01
0.02
32
1.01
PK
4.20
9.57
14.30
10.00
12.40
19.30
80.90
3.32
1.94
8.56
0.00
29
0.91
30
(Annex A - continued) PL
3.90
5.86
15.68
15.10
10.90
16.30
80.60
1.10
2.77
3.99
0.00
33
1.04
PT
1.10
3.00
QA
14.70
4.90
16.20
8.00
12.20
23.60
70.50
1.20
2.69
4.77
0.07
20
0.63
16.04
22.80
17.40
20.00
76.20
0.49
3.45
0.40
0.00
5
0.16
RU
3.40
4.82
16.20
16.70
15.40
23.20
60.40
2.86
2.33
6.43
0.14
27
0.85
SA
6.30
1.24
17.02
12.90
13.30
14.30
81.80
0.86
2.77
0.40
0.00
8
0.25
SE
2.40
3.36
16.76
8.50
13.10
25.10
60.30
2.12
2.24
3.50
0.07
21
0.66
SG
5.80
1.83
15.55
9.50
32.90
20.40
63.00
0.31
3.48
3.25
0.00
29
0.91
SI
-0.30
1.69
15.66
2.70
7.00
9.80
78.90
4.20
1.18
4.81
0.22
2
0.06
SK
4.10
3.28
15.59
5.90
8.20
15.30
78.80
2.46
2.48
16.25
0.03
5
0.16
TH
4.20
3.78
14.56
10.10
24.50
14.60
69.20
2.05
1.80
4.02
0.03
51
1.61
TR
4.60
32.78
16.08
21.70
14.60
20.40
72.30
2.02
2.18
3.21
0.06
30
0.94
TW
4.00
2.98
15.70
5.90
20.60
19.40
63.50
1.17
2.62
2.60
0.00
67
2.11
US
2.30
2.84
15.49
10.60
9.90
9.70
72.50
1.57
3.00
6.74
0.08
1,212
38.15
VE
3.50
15.24
14.96
30.30
10.40
25.00
85.40
1.68
2.22
7.19
0.00
11
0.35
ZA
3.50
8.94
14.59
9.50
40.80
22.80
56.80
0.90
2.56
5.48
0.00
26
0.82
ZW
-10.10
123.07
11.67
38.90
19.30
41.80
64.60
1.66
0.82
0.48
0.00
4
0.13
2.70 4.41 15.77 9.70 14.20 16.70 71.40 1.39 2.70 4.48 0.05 3,177 100.00 Total Sources: Bloomberg, OECD, Eurostat, Datastream, Moody's KMV, Creditedge and BIS. Advanced economies are indicated in italics. Notes: (1) The Z-score is an indicator of the probability of default which is computed on the base of balance sheet variables. The methodology is described in Altman et al (1994). (2) EDF change for the non-financial sector in a country. The source is Moody’s KMV. (3) Banks analysed in this table refer to the final dataset after the filtering process and other corrections. (4) As a percentage of the number of observations.
31
Annex B: Additional details on the construction of the database on macroprudential tools Our primary data sources for macroprudential measures are Shim et al (2013) and Lim et al (2011, 2013). The first data base covers policy actions on housing markets for 60 economies worldwide from January 1990 (or earliest date available) to June 2012. It draws on a variety of sources including official documents from central banks’ and regulatory authorities’ annual reports, financial stability reports, monetary policy bulletins. Shim et al (2013) complement and cross-check official sources and documents with Borio and Shim (2007), survey by the Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS) on macroprudential policy conducted in December 2009, Hilbers et al (2005), Crowe et al (2011), Lim et al (2011), and Tovar et al (2012). Thus, the database covers a wide range of countries and measures, as well as a long time span on macro-prudential measures. The policy actions in the database are categorized under general and targeted credit policy measures including minimum reserve requirements, liquidity requirements and limits on credit growth, maximum loan-to-value ratios, maximum debt-service-to-income ratios, risk weights on housing loans, provisioning requirements (general loan-loss provisioning ratios and specific provisioning ratios applied to housing loans) and exposure limits on banks to the housing sector. While the main aim of Shim et al (2013) is to document policy actions related to the housing market, they also include measure in the data set even if a central bank or another other authority changes policy decision for reasons other than the state of the housing market. Thus, their data set contains prudential measures taken from both microprudential and macroprudential perspectives. The second study that we use to construct macro-prudential measures is Lim et al (2013) which is based on the 2010 IMF survey on Financial Stability and Macroprudential Policy. Lim et al (2013) update and extend the survey to assess if institutional arrangements can affect the timely use of macroprudential policy instruments by evaluating policy response time under different institutional arrangements for a sample of 39 countries. Another study that also uses the IMF survey in 2010 is Lim et al (2011) that provides a comprehensive empirical study on the effectiveness of macroprudential instruments by using data from 49 countries over the period of 2000-2010. The IMF survey and both reference studies identify 10 instruments that have been most frequently applied to achieve macroprudential objective that is “to limit the risk of widespread disruptions to the provision of financial services and thereby minimize the impact of such disruptions on the economy as a whole.” (IMF, 2011, pp 7). These instruments are classified as credit-related ( ie, caps on the loan-to-value ratio, caps on the debt-to-income ratio, caps on foreign currency lending and ceilings on credit or credit growth); liquidity-related (i.e. limits on net open currency positions/currency mismatch, limits on maturity mismatch and reserve requirements), and capital-related (i.e. countercyclical/time-varying capital requirements, time-varying/dynamic provisioning, and restrictions on profit distribution) measures. Using the two sources above we construct a database of macro-prudential measures for 64 countries from 1990 to 2012. The macro-prudential measures are classified under 10 categories including credit growth limits (Credit), liquidity requirements (Liq), maximum debt-service-to-income ratio and other lending criteria (DSTI), capital requirement/risk weights (RW), provisioning requirement (Prov), limits on banks’ exposure to the housing sector (Expo), reserve requirement (RR), maximum loanto-value ratio and loan prohibition (LTV), limits on net open position (NOP), and foreign currency lending limits (FCL). If a policy action is covered by both Shim et al (2013) and Lim et al (2013), then we compare and cross-checks both data bases, and include additional measures such as limits on net open positions and foreign currency lending as these instruments are not directly or indirectly aiming policy actions on housing markets. The set of instruments covered here would capture broad categories of systemic risk that could be linked to risk-taking channel such as risks arising from strong credit growth
32
and credit-driven asset price inflation, excessive leverage and the consequent deleveraging, systemic liquidity risk, and risks related to large and volatile capital flows, including foreign currency lending. Given the heterogeneity across policy instruments and actions, we follow Kuttner and Shim (2013) to create monthly variables that take on three discrete values: 1 for tightening actions, –1 for loosening actions and 0 for no change. Since the frequency of bank level and macroeconomic data used in our study is annual, then the monthly observations are summed to create yearly time series. Thus, both policy action’s intensity and their directions would be captured by summing monthly data over each year which could take value of -1 or 1; -2 or 2; -3 or 3, and up to -12 or 12 or more. When macroprudential index is constructed for each instrument, and tightening and easing actions are aggregated over the year, then actions in opposite directions may cancel each other leaving with no net change. In final analysis, we investigate also the impact of easing and tightening separately using indicator variable 0 or 1 (no change or change in policy measure). Based on our coding we observe 1,047 policy actions associated with ten different types of macroprudential tools (see Table 3). Among these policy measures reserve requirements are the most frequently used ones followed by loan-to-value ratio and capital requirements/risk weights. The reason for the frequent changes in reserve requirements is that this policy tools could be used for broad purposed, and could directly influence the liquidity conditions in the market. Additionally, in same cases in emerging economies, it also serves as capital flow management device by setting higher rates on foreign currency and external short term funding of the banking sector or longer maintenance period for certain types of liabilities.
33
Annex C: Robustness checks Table C1: Baseline regression with aggregate macroprudential index (only advanced economies) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) (II) Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (III) (IV) Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.350
***
0.0184
0.343
***
0.0136
0.944
***
0.0519
0.976
***
0.0178
EDF_NFSt
0.264
***
0.0530
0.350
***
0.0772
0.029
***
0.0068
0.006
***
0.0020
**
0.0488
-0.022
***
0.0055
-0.024
**
0.0095
-0.010
**
0.0046
1.5823
-1.186
1.4491
-0.772
***
0.2571
-0.475
***
0.0402
0.0060
-0.027
0.0050
-0.014
**
0.0061
-0.027
***
0.0048
DIFFt
-0.099
GDPt
-0.840
SIZEt-1
-0.015
**
LIQt-1
-0.265
**
0.1071
-0.191
***
0.0349
-0.135
***
0.0337
-0.130
***
0.0077
CAPt-1
-0.586
***
0.0211
-0.778
***
0.1834
-0.426
***
0.1455
-0.832
***
0.1898
DEPt-1
-0.472
***
0.1722
-0.558
***
0.1869
-0.613
***
0.1007
-0.999
***
0.1797
MP_indext
-0.469
**
0.1958
-0.672
*
0.3939
-0.072
**
0.0364
-0.169
***
0.0193
MP_indext*CAP t-1
1.629
*
0.8792
0.726
**
0.3232
MP_indext*SIZE t-1
0.189
***
0.0666
0.066
**
0.0273
MP_indext*LIQ t-1
0.430
**
0.1852
0.256
***
0.0329
0.476
***
0.1613
MP_indext*DEP t-1 Sample period
***
1.235
1.1886
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
Observations
15,114
15,114
15,114
15,114
Serial correlation test1
0.076
0.078
0.16
0.138
Hansen test2
0.229
0.11
0.123
0.11
Notes: The database is composed of 2,286 banks headquartered in advanced economies. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
34
Table C2: Cyclical vs Resilience macroprudential tools (only advanced economies) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) Coeff Std err
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (II) Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.286
***
0.0147
0.948
***
0.1653
EDF_NFSt
0.035
***
0.0095
0.430
**
0.1740
DIFFt
-0.090
***
0.0176
-0.035
***
0.0075
GDPt
-1.276
1.8909
-0.571
**
0.2319
SIZEt-1
-0.023
**
0.0105
-0.010
***
0.0037
LIQt-1
-0.298
**
0.1423
-0.260
*
0.1458
CAPt-1
-0.785
**
0.3883
-0.257
***
0.0096
DEPt-1
-0.575
**
0.2649
-0.483
***
0.0925
MP_cyclical indext
-0.596
***
0.0659
-0.102
***
0.0162
MP_resilience_indext
***
0.0229
***
0.0013
-0.246
***
0.0344
-0.066
MP_Cyclical indext * CAPt-1
1.358
***
0.1562
0.128
MP_Cyclical indext * SIZEt-1
0.160
***
0.0287
0.076
MP_Cyclical indext * LIQt-1
0.747
0.4618
0.151
MP_Cyclical indext * DEPt-1
0.542
**
0.2677
0.066
**
0.0290
MP_ Resilience indext * CAPt-1
2.673
***
0.6203
0.212
**
0.0933
MP_ Resilience indext * SIZEt-1
0.062
***
0.0180
0.044
***
0.0138
MP_ Resilience indext * LIQt-1
0.706
**
0.3490
1.561
**
0.6202
MP_ Resilience indext * DEPt-1
1.689 ** 1990-2012
0.7612
0.185 *** 1990-2012
Sample period Observations Serial correlation test
0.0875 0.1494
15,114
15,114
0.089
0.129
1
Hansen test2
0.0521
0.558 0.278 Notes: The database is composed of 2,286 banks headquartered in advanced economies. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
35
Table C3: Baseline regression with aggregate macroprudential index (only emerging market economies) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) (II) Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (III) (IV) Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.067
***
0.003
0.218
***
0.036
0.887
***
0.059
0.880
***
0.063
EDF_NFSt
0.895
***
0.026
0.702
***
0.254
0.038
**
0.015
0.032
***
0.007
DIFFt
-0.064
***
0.019
-0.014
**
0.007
-0.001
***
0.000
-0.002
*
0.001
GDPt
-0.952
*
0.522
-1.201
*
0.729
-0.441
*
0.240
-0.313
**
0.151
SIZEt-1
-0.060
***
0.017
-0.113
***
0.039
-0.012
***
0.004
-0.016
***
0.003
LIQt-1
-0.009
0.088
0.199
0.360
-0.236
***
0.059
-0.383
**
0.150
CAPt-1
-1.849
**
0.921
-2.319
***
0.579
-0.733
**
0.287
-0.362
**
0.178
DEPt-1
-1.784
**
0.774
-1.730
***
0.439
-0.868
***
0.254
-0.555
***
0.175
MP_indext
-0.158
***
0.017
-0.073
***
0.005
-0.883
***
0.051
-0.024
**
0.012
MP_indext*CAP t-1
2.784
***
0.056
0.556
***
0.188
MP_indext*SIZE t-1
0.303
**
0.146
0.004
***
0.000
MP_indext*LIQ t-1
0.340
0.343
0.095
*
0.055
0.509
***
0.128
MP_indext*DEP t-1
0.679
Sample period Observations Serial correlation test Hansen test2
1
***
0.022
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
5,756
5,756
5,756
5,756
0.089
0.156
0.359
0.348
0.706
0.169
0.177
0.248
Notes: The database is composed of 891 banks headquartered in emerging market economies. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
36
Table C4: Cyclical vs Resilience macroprudential tools (only emerging market economies) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) Coeff
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (II)
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.0225
**
0.0106
0.8579
***
0.0401
EDF_NFSt
0.4014
***
0.0892
0.0572
***
0.0068
DIFFt
-0.0050
**
0.0022
-0.0043
***
0.0015
GDPt
-1.3650
*
0.7523
-0.6346
***
0.0489
SIZEt-1
-0.0684
**
0.0270
-0.0313
***
0.0022
LIQt-1
-0.2692
***
0.0404
-0.2651
***
0.0873
CAPt-1
-0.1816
***
0.0620
-0.3468
***
0.0882
DEPt-1
-0.0492
0.0881
-0.3023
**
0.1262
MP_cyclical indext
-0.2715
***
0.0557
-0.0885
***
0.0142
MP_resilience_indext
-0.0129
**
0.0052
-0.0532
***
0.0004
MP_Cyclical indext *C APt-1
4.5583
***
0.6487
0.5115
**
0.2416
MP_Cyclical indext * SIZEt-1
0.4135
***
0.0753
0.0430
***
0.0137
MP_Cyclical indext * LIQt-1
0.0933
0.4506
0.0967
MP_Cyclical indext * DEPt-1
1.0434
***
0.1613
0.1406
***
0.0217
MP_ Resilience indext * CAPt-1
1.5232
***
0.3118
0.5416
***
0.1774
MP_ Resilience indext * SIZEt-1
0.0447
***
0.0035
0.0242
***
MP_ Resilience indext * LIQt-1
0.9982
***
0.0235
0.0001
MP_ Resilience indext * DEPt-1
0.5627
***
0.0440
0.1936
Sample period
***
1990-2012
5,756
5,756
1
Hansen test
2
0.0009 0.0093
1990-2012
Observations Serial correlation test
0.1879
0.163
0.406
0.158
0.100
0.0073
Notes: The database is composed of 891 banks headquartered in emerging market economies. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
37
Table C5: Baseline regression with aggregate macroprudential index (only pre-crisis period) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) (II) Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (III) (IV) Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.097
**
0.039
0.104
***
0.018
0.921
***
0.015
0.946
***
0.018
EDF_NFSt
0.176
**
0.069
0.387
**
0.173
0.012
**
0.005
0.006
*
0.003
***
**
DIFFt
-0.014
0.001
-0.014
0.006
-0.004
**
0.002
-0.007
***
0.002
GDPt
-1.997
1.546
-1.562
2.095
-0.941
**
0.411
-0.959
***
0.359
SIZEt-1
-0.006
0.012
0.002
0.014
-0.020
**
0.010
-0.018
**
0.008
LIQt-1
-0.192
***
0.010
-0.154
0.197
-0.058
**
0.029
0.019
CAPt-1
-0.770
**
0.388
-9.946
***
1.978
-0.793
***
0.073
-0.622
***
0.052
DEPt-1
-0.777
*
0.433
-2.186
***
0.627
-0.972
**
0.396
-0.793
**
0.339
MP_indext
-0.053
**
0.027
-0.036
**
0.017
-0.097
**
0.039
0.234
***
0.052
0.045
-0.066
**
0.029
MP_indext*CAP t-1
1.887
***
0.591
MP_indext*SIZE t-1
0.051
***
0.015
0.038
***
0.008
MP_indext*LIQ t-1
0.213
*
0.119
0.190
**
0.087
2.045
***
0.757
0.037
*
0.020
MP_indext*DEP t-1 Sample period Observations Serial correlation test Hansen test2
1
1990-2007
1990-2007
1990-2007
1990-2007
13,460
13,460
13,460
13,460
0.061
0.056
0.064
0.104
0.155
0.170
0.147
0.429
Notes: The database is composed of 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries. We include only observations for the pre-crisis period. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
38
Table C6: Cyclical vs Resilience macroprudential tools (only pre-crisis period) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) Coeff Std err
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (II) Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.182
***
0.0117
0.894
***
0.0644
EDF_NFSt
0.138
**
0.0698
0.041
***
0.0136
DIFFt
-0.007
*
0.0038
-0.021
***
0.0038
GDPt
-1.945
1.1855
-0.864
*
0.4827
SIZEt-1
-0.013
**
0.0068
-0.011
*
0.0057
LIQt-1
-0.242
***
0.0070
-0.101
CAPt-1
-0.842
**
0.3602
-0.355
DEPt-1
-0.795
**
0.3959
-0.470
MP_Cyclical indext
-0.742
***
0.0786
-0.023
**
0.0096
MP_Resilience_indext
-0.043
**
0.0175
-0.019
***
0.0026
MP_Cyclical indext * CAPt-1
1.666
***
0.0281
0.579
***
0.0910
MP_Cyclical indext * SIZEt-1
0.242
*
0.1288
0.010
MP_Cyclical indext * LIQt-1
0.039
0.0358
0.148
**
0.0695
MP_Cyclical indext * DEPt-1
0.321
***
0.0700
0.100
MP_ Resilience indext * CAPt-1
0.836
**
0.3958
0.587
**
0.2558
MP_ Resilience indext * SIZEt-1
0.035
*
0.0198
0.020
***
0.0038
MP_ Resilience indext * LIQt-1
0.347
***
0.1077
0.161
***
0.0315
MP_ Resilience indext * DEPt-1
0.961
***
0.3248
0.181
**
0.0858
Sample period Observations Serial correlation test
0.1319 **
0.0099 0.0657
1990-2007
1990-2007
13,460
13,460
0.069
0.053
1
Hansen test2
0.1588 0.2918
0.758 0.114 Notes: The database is composed of 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries. We include only observations for the pre-crisis period. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
39
Table C7: Baseline regression with aggregate macroprudential index (including time dummies) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) (II) Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (III) (IV) Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.258
***
0.034
0.167
***
0.048
0.880
***
0.077
0.900
***
0.190
EDF_NFSt
0.770
***
0.099
1.318
***
0.055
0.088
***
0.017
0.081
***
0.020
-0.005
***
**
0.014
-0.015
**
0.007
-0.015
***
0.004
1.103
-1.548
***
0.136
-1.248
**
0.558
0.004
-0.019
DIFFt
0.002
-0.035
GDPt
0.644
1.199
-1.200
SIZEt-1
-0.022
0.014
-0.092
***
0.021
-0.028
***
LIQt-1
-0.232
***
0.034
-0.599
***
0.120
-0.041
**
0.018
-0.070
CAPt-1
-0.374
***
0.145
-1.534
***
0.192
-1.082
***
0.122
-0.579
**
0.226
DEPt-1
-0.174
**
0.075
-1.123
***
0.243
-1.170
***
0.215
-0.753
**
0.312
MP_indext
-0.346
**
0.161
-0.023
**
0.010
-0.062
**
0.031
0.129
*
0.067
**
-1.702
*
0.879
MP_indext*CAP t-1
14.992
**
6.133
MP_indext*SIZE t-1
0.404
**
MP_indext*LIQ t-1
3.375
MP_indext*DEP t-1
11.556
**
0.171
0.006
2.803
0.152
5.139
0.340
0.015 0.059
0.003 0.095
**
Time dummies
yes
yes
yes
yes
Sample period
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
Observations
20,870
20,870
20,870
20,870
Serial correlation test1
0.092
0.096
0.084
0.126
Hansen test2
0.716
0.720
0.054
0.178
0.163
Notes: The database is composed of 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
40
Table C8: Cyclical vs Resilience macroprudential tools (including time dummies) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) Coeff Std err
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (II) Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.201
***
0.0215
0.903
***
0.2174
EDF_NFSt
0.540
***
0.1792
0.125
***
0.0414
DIFFt
-0.029
***
0.0082
-0.025
**
0.0100
GDPt
-1.237
1.1132
-1.933
*
1.1591
SIZEt-1
-0.064
*
0.0382
-0.017
**
0.0083
LIQt-1
-0.556
**
0.2278
-0.218
**
0.1048
CAPt-1
-2.117
***
0.5128
-0.488
***
0.0530
DEPt-1
-1.680
***
0.6314
-0.607
***
0.0951
MP_Cyclical indext
-1.040
**
0.4599
-0.200
***
0.0330
MP_Resilience_indext
-0.068
*
0.0350
-0.063
**
0.0295
0.5582
1.141
***
0.0188
MP_Cyclical indext * CAPt-1
3.502
***
MP_Cyclical indext * SIZEt-1
0.317
**
0.1286
0.058
MP_Cyclical indext * LIQt-1
0.103
*
0.0624
0.345
MP_Cyclical indext * DEPt-1
0.891
**
0.4496
0.084
MP_ Resilience indext * CAPt-1
1.357
***
0.5073
0.719
***
0.0400
MP_ Resilience indext * SIZEt-1
0.019
0.0397
0.024
**
0.0114
MP_ Resilience indext * LIQt-1
0.297
*
0.1667
0.219
*
0.1274
MP_ Resilience indext * DEPt-1
1.383
**
0.5877
0.238
***
0.0397
0.0385 **
0.0562
Time dummies
yes
yes
Sample period
1990-2012
1990-2012
Observations
20,870
20,870
Serial correlation test1
0.152
0.294
Hansen test2
0.1373
0.738 0.141 Notes: The database is composed of 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
41
Table C9: Baseline regression with aggregate macroprudential index (including country*time dummies) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) (II) Coeff Dependent variablet-1
Std err
0.240
**
0.1187
Coeff
Std err
0.253
SIZEt-1
-0.016
*
0.0080
-0.137
LIQt-1
-0.045
*
0.0235
-0.255
CAPt-1
-0.857
*
0.4446
-1.320
DEPt-1
-0.582
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (III) (IV) Coeff
Std err
0.346
***
0.0650
Coeff
Std err
***
0.0095
*
0.0786
-0.034
**
0.0136
-0.021
***
0.0013
0.4417
-0.958
**
0.4120
-0.040
*
0.0207
**
0.5482
-0.505
**
0.2034
-0.482
***
0.0195
*
0.3117
-0.458
***
0.1709
-0.572
*
0.3117
0.963
**
0.4728
***
0.0049
-0.660
**
0.3117
MP_indext*CAP t-1
0.824
**
0.3892
MP_indext*SIZE t-1
0.012
**
0.0048
0.041
*
0.0247
MP_indext*LIQ t-1
0.358
**
0.1683
0.223
**
0.1067
MP_indext*DEP t-1
1.290
**
0.5108
0.025
**
0.0124
0.898
MP_Cyclical indext * CAPt-1
0.659
***
0.1603
0.144
MP_Cyclical indext * SIZEt-1
0.057
**
0.0226
0.005
***
0.1027
0.0047
MP_Cyclical indext * LIQt-1
0.287
0.2443
0.033
***
0.0100
MP_Cyclical indext * DEPt-1
0.516
***
0.0010
0.175
***
0.0047
MP_ Resilience indext * CAPt-1
3.362
***
1.1490
0.595
***
0.0407
MP_ Resilience indext * SIZEt-1
0.090
*
0.0525
0.005
0.0068
MP_ Resilience indext * LIQt-1
0.120
0.2813
0.141
0.0954
MP_ Resilience indext * DEPt-1 Country*Time dummies Sample period
2.267
***
0.8440
0.380
***
yes
yes
yes
yes
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
1990-2012
Observations
20,870
20,870
20,870
20,870
Serial correlation test1
0.077
0.094
0.194
0.0754
Hansen test2
0.0549
0.138 0.229 0.123 0.329 Notes: The database is composed of 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank-year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
42
Table C10: Baseline regression with aggregate macroprudential index (controlling for regulatory strength) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) (II) Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (III) (IV) Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.238
***
0.006
0.244
***
0.005
0.894
***
0.028
0.912
***
0.018
EDF_NFSt
0.445
***
0.073
0.491
***
0.125
0.015
***
0.003
0.020
***
0.002
**
0.009
-0.020
**
0.009
-0.007
**
0.003
-0.010
**
0.004
0.858
-1.374
0.928
-0.696
***
0.039
-0.655
***
0.039
**
0.009
-0.012
**
0.005
DIFFt
-0.022
GDPt
-0.355
SIZEt-1
-0.019
***
0.005
-0.039
**
0.019
-0.019
LIQt-1
-0.123
***
0.016
-0.129
**
0.059
-0.035
0.042
-0.060
*
0.032
CAPt-1
-0.420
***
0.139
-0.572
***
0.218
-0.765
***
0.024
-0.401
***
0.014
DEPt-1
-0.224
**
0.092
-0.277
**
0.127
-0.873
***
0.199
-0.545
***
0.069
MP_indext
-0.659
***
0.062
-0.810
-0.015
***
0.003
-0.022
***
0.245
***
0.005
MP_indext*CAP t-1
1.246
***
0.060
0.169
***
0.003
MP_indext*SIZE t-1
0.157
***
0.031
0.008
**
0.004
MP_indext*LIQ t-1
0.332
*
0.178
0.218
*
0.112
MP_indext*DEP t-1
0.247
*
0.127
0.118
***
0.015
*
0.1241
0.294
**
0.120
0.291
**
0.146
***
0.2360
-0.574
***
0.180
-0.173
*
0.099
Banking crisis index Regulat. strength index Sample period
0.283 -2.804
**
0.1108
0.224
***
0.3459
-1.641
1999-2012
1999-2012
1999-2012
1999-2012
Observations
16,615
16,615
16,615
16,615
Serial correlation test1
0.109
0.116
0.112
0.136
Hansen test2
0.426
0.443
0.164
0.118
Notes: The database is composed of 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank-year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals.
43
Table C11: Cyclical vs Resilience macroprudential tools (controlling for regulatory strength) Dependent variable: Annual change of the expected default frequency over a 1 year horizon (I) Coeff
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score (II)
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.089
**
0.043
0.890
***
0.067
EDF_NFSt
0.614
***
0.090
0.032
***
0.005
DIFFt
-0.041
**
GDPt
-1.517
SIZEt-1
-0.053
LIQt-1 CAPt-1
0.019
-0.018
***
0.004
2.442
-0.768
***
0.261
*
0.027
-0.012
**
0.005
-0.278
***
0.015
-0.158
***
0.060
-1.711
***
0.507
-0.425
***
0.112
DEPt-1
-1.299
***
0.192
-0.547
***
0.100
MP_Cyclical indext
-0.473
**
0.194
-0.037
*
0.020
MP_Resilience_indext
-0.158
***
0.042
-0.066
***
0.001
MP_Cyclical indext * CAPt-1
1.510
***
0.434
0.568
***
0.145
MP_Cyclical indext * SIZEt-1
0.125
*
0.067
0.009
*
0.005
MP_Cyclical indext * LIQt-1
0.551
***
0.010
0.162
***
0.040
MP_Cyclical indext * DEPt-1
0.545
**
0.237
0.117
*
0.069
MP_ Resilience indext * CAPt-1
2.056
**
0.913
0.621
***
0.183
MP_ Resilience indext * SIZEt-1
0.088
**
0.035
0.031
***
0.006
MP_ Resilience indext * LIQt-1
0.304
*
0.158
0.104
*
0.058
MP_ Resilience indext * DEPt-1
1.501
**
0.737
0.101
***
0.020
Banking crisis index
0.089
**
0.043
0.890
***
0.067
Regulatory strength index
0.614
***
0.090
0.032
***
0.005
Sample period Observations Serial correlation test
1999-2012
1999-2012
16,615
16,615
0.152
0.274
1
Hansen test 0.738 0.741 Notes: The database is composed of 3,177 banks headquartered in 61 countries. Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. 1 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals. 2
44
Table C12: Using only Z-score as dependent variable to enlarge the sample Baseline regression with aggregate macroprudential index
Cyclical vs Resilience macroprudential tools
(I)
(II)
Dependent variable: Annual change of the Z-score Coeff
Std err
Coeff
Std err
Dependent variablet-1
0.921
***
0.0140
0.901
***
0.0359
EDF_NFSt
0.0059
0.023
***
0.0004
0.017
***
DIFFt
-0.004
**
0.0015
-0.006
***
0.0019
GDPt
-0.228
***
0.0254
-0.645
***
0.0254
SIZEt-1
-0.004
***
0.0012
-0.010
*
0.0053
LIQt-1
-0.121
**
0.0581
-0.119
*
0.0659
CAPt-1
-0.533
***
0.1480
-1.106
***
0.0825
DEPt-1
-0.871
**
0.4276
-1.408
***
0.1500
MP_indext
-0.019
***
0.0064
MP_indext*CAP t-1
0.013
***
0.0037
MP_indext*SIZE t-1
0.008
**
MP_indext*LIQ t-1
0.127
MP_indext*DEP t-1
0.112
MP_Cyclical indext
-0.046
**
0.0212
MP_Resilience_indext
-0.024
***
0.0052
0.0041 0.0828
***
0.0221
MP_Cyclical indext * CAPt-1
0.385
***
0.0376
MP_Cyclical indext * SIZEt-1
0.005
**
0.0024
MP_Cyclical indext * LIQt-1
0.017
MP_Cyclical indext * DEPt-1
0.010
MP_ Resilience indext * CAPt-1
0.136
MP_ Resilience indext * SIZEt-1 MP_ Resilience indext * LIQt-1 MP_ Resilience indext * DEPt-1 Sample period Observations Serial correlation test1
0.0275 0.0070 ***
0.0183
0.011
***
0.0022
0.293
**
0.1430
0.212
**
0.1068
1990-2012
1990-2012
115,611
115,611
0.115
0.104
Hansen test
0.129 0.133 Notes: Robust standard errors (clustered at the bank year level) are reported. The symbols *, **, and *** represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. The coefficient for the banking crisis dummy is not reported. 1Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no second order serial correlation. 2 Reports p-values for the null hypothesis that the instruments used are not correlated with the residuals. 2
45
Previous volumes in this series No
Title
Author
645 June 2017
Accounting for debt service: the painful legacy of credit booms
Mathias Drehmann, Mikael Juselius and Anton Korinek
644 June 2017
The shifting drivers of global liquidity
Stefan Avdjiev, Leonardo Gambacorta, Linda S. Goldberg and Stefano Schiaffi
643 June 2017
The international dimensions of macroprudential policies
Pierre-Richard Agénor, Enisse Kharroubi, Leonardo Gambacorta, Giovanni Lombardo and Luiz Pereira da Silva
642 June 2017
The effects of monetary policy shocks on inequality in Japan
Masayuki Inui, Nao Sudo and Tomoaki Yamada
641 May 2017
China’s evolving monetary policy rule: from inflation-accommodating to anti-inflation policy
Eric Girardin, Sandrine Lunven and Guonan Ma
640 May 2017
Understanding the determinants of financial outcomes and choices: the role of noncognitive abilities
Gianpaolo Parise and Kim Peijnenburg
639 May 2017
Supply- and demand-side factors in global banking
Mary Amiti, Patrick McGuire and David E Weinstein
638 May 2017
Assessing fiscal policy through the lens of the Enrique Alberola and Ricardo Sousa financial and the commodity price cycles
637 May 2017
Global value chains and effective exchange rates at the country-sector level
Nikhil Patel, Zhi Wang and ShangJin Wei
636 May 2017
The impact of macroprudential policies and their interaction with monetary policy: an empirical analysis using credit registry data
Leonardo Gambacorta and Andrés Murcia
635 May 2017
Prudential policies and their impact on credit in the United States
Paul Calem, Ricardo Correa and Seung Jung Lee
634 May 2017
Evaluating the impact of macroprudential policies on credit growth in Colombia
Esteban Gómez, Angélica Lizarazo, Juan Carlos Mendoza and Andrés Murcia
633 May 2017
The impact of warnings published in a financial stability report on loan-to-value ratios
Andrés Alegría, Rodrigo Alfaro and Felipe Córdova
632 May 2017
The impact of macroprudential housing finance tools in Canada
Jason Allen, Timothy Grieder, Brian Peterson and Tom Roberts
631 April 2017
Jacob Gyntelberg, Peter Hördahl, Arbitrage costs and the persistent non-zero CDS-bond basis: Evidence from intraday euro Kristyna Ters and Jörg Urban area sovereign debt markets
All volumes are available on our website www.bis.org.
46