Preference for Flexibility and Bayesian Updating - Banco Central

0 downloads 0 Views 380KB Size Report
57 As Leis de Falência: uma Abordagem Econômica. Aloisio Araujo. Dez/2002. 58. The Random Walk Hypothesis and the Behavior of Foreign Capital. Portfolio ...
ISSN 1518-3548

177

Working Paper Series

Preference for Flexibility and Bayesian Updating Gil Riella December, 2008

ISSN 1518-3548 CGC 00.038.166/0001-05 Working Paper Series

Brasília

n. 177

Dec.

2008

p. 1-57

Working Paper Series

Edited by Research Department (Depep) – E-mail: [email protected] Editor: Benjamin Miranda Tabak – E-mail: [email protected] Editorial Assistent: Jane Sofia Moita – E-mail: [email protected] Head of Research Department: Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo – E-mail: [email protected] The Banco Central do Brasil Working Papers are all evaluated in double blind referee process. Reproduction is permitted only if source is stated as follows: Working Paper n. 177. Authorized by Mário Mesquita, Deputy Governor for Economic Policy.

General Control of Publications Banco Central do Brasil Secre/Surel/Dimep SBS – Quadra 3 – Bloco B – Edifício-Sede – 1º andar Caixa Postal 8.670 70074-900 Brasília – DF – Brazil Phones: +55 (61) 3414-3710 and 3414-3567 Fax: +55 (61) 3414-3626 E-mail: [email protected]

The views expressed in this work are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Banco Central or its members. Although these Working Papers often represent preliminary work, citation of source is required when used or reproduced.

As opiniões expressas neste trabalho são exclusivamente do(s) autor(es) e não refletem, necessariamente, a visão do Banco Central do Brasil. Ainda que este artigo represente trabalho preliminar, citação da fonte é requerida mesmo quando reproduzido parcialmente.

Consumer Complaints and Public Enquiries Center Banco Central do Brasil Secre/Surel/Diate SBS – Quadra 3 – Bloco B – Edifício-Sede – 2º subsolo 70074-900 Brasília – DF – Brazil Fax: +55 (61) 3414-2553 Internet: http//www.bcb.gov.br/?english

Preference for Flexibility and Bayesian Updating Gil Riellay

Abstract

The Working Papers should not be reported as representing the views of the Banco Central do Brasil. The views expressed in the papers are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily re‡ect those of the Banco Central do Brasil.

Dekel, Lipman, and Rustichini (2001) show that preferences over menus of lotteries can be represented by the use of a unique subjective state space and a prior. We provide foundations for Bayesian updating in such a setup. When the subjective state space is …nite, we show that Bayesian updating is linked to a comparative theory of preference for ‡exibility. Without the …niteness of the subjective state space, Bayesian updating is characterized by a more technical condition. JEL Classi…cation: D11, D81. Keywords: Preference for Flexibility, Bayesian Updating, Subjective State Space.

I thank Ozgur Evren, Leandro Nascimento, Pietro Ortoleva, Debraj Ray and participants in the NRET workshop at NYU for helpful discussions and suggestions. I especially thank Efe Ok for his support and advice during all stages of this work. Finally, I gratefully acknowledge the …nancial support of the Capes foundation and Banco Central do Brasil. y Research Department, Banco Central do Brasil. E-mail: [email protected] and [email protected]

3

1

Introduction

The issue of updating ones preferences on uncertain alternatives on the face of additional information is a topic that is extensively studied in individual decision theory. In particular, the Bayesian underpinnings of such updating are well understood within the realm of the Savagean theory of decision making, where the state space is regarded as exogenously given. When, however, the decision model at hand regards the state space as endogenous, as in the recently developed dynamic theory of choice over menus, the foundations for the notion of Bayesian updating become much less transparent. In a nutshell, the paper is an attempt to provide such a foundation by using the notion of preference for ‡exibility. Consider the following situation. At 11 AM Jane has to choose a place for her evening drink with her friends. Suppose the only way places vary is in the menu of drinks they o¤er and Jane always has only one drink. Let X be the set of all possible drinks and X be the set of all conceivable drink menus, each menu being represented by capital letters A; B; C; etc.. As in Kreps (1979), we assume that Jane has a well-de…ned preference relation % on X and this relation exhibits preference for ‡exibility in the sense that, for any two menus A and B, A

B implies A % B:

Moreover, we assume that her preferences admit the following representation: A % B i¤

X s2S

(s) max U (x; s) x2A

X s2S

(s) max U (x; s) ; x2B

(1)

where S is a …nite state-space, is a probability measure on S and U is a statedependent utility function. The interpretation is that Jane is uncertain about the future and, in particular, she is not sure what kind of drink she will be in the mood for in the evening. The representation above thus says that she chooses a place that maximizes the expected utility she can get from the place’s drink menu, with respect to some prior about her future tastes. At lunch, Jane will meet with her friends and one of them is going to be selected as the designated driver for the evening. If Jane gets to be the designated driver, and only in that situation, she would very much appreciate if the place they went had orange juice, with the other drinks being unimportant. We represent the “Jane being the designated driver situation” by the state s 2 S. If we use the letter j 4

to represent the orange juice alternative, the discussion above can be formalized as follows: U (j; s ) > U (x; s ) and U (y; s ) = U (x; s ) ; for all x; y 2 X distinct from j, and U (j; s) < U (x; s) ; for all x 2 X and s 2 S, distinct from j and s , respectively. Suppose, now, instead of choosing a place in the morning, Jane …rst goes for lunch with her friends and at that occasion she is informed that she will not have to drive that evening. In terms of the representation above, this is equivalent to say that she learns that the state s will not happen. Finally, we assume that Jane is Bayesian, so, upon learning that state s is no longer a possibility, she uses Bayes rule to update her prior about the states of the world. Except for that, she follows (1) to make her decision about where to go for drinks in the evening. The situation described in the previous paragraphs is entirely standard in economics. Indeed, were the state-space S observable by the modeler, we could easily axiomatize Jane’s Bayesian behavior by a Dynamic Consistency like condition. However, in the preference over menus literature, the state-space is not part of the speci…cation of the model, being instead derived as part of the representation of the agent’s preferences. For that reason, an axiomatization of Bayesian updating in the present setting is bound to be related to conditions that have a completely di¤erent interpretation. The main goal of the present paper is to provide such an axiomatization and discuss the conditions related to Bayesian updating when the primitives of our model consist of preference relations over a space of menus. Obviously, without an exogenously speci…ed state-space, we cannot write a condition that explicitly deals with the fact that Jane receives new information at lunch. Nonetheless, the fact that she is Bayesian still implies some consistency conditions relating her preferences before and after lunch. To organize the discussion, let %1 represent her preference before lunch and %2 the one after lunch. Now suppose that A and B are two menus such that A 2 B, but B %1 A. That is, before lunch she considers menu B at least as good as menu A, but after she learns that she will not have to drive in the evening, menu A becomes strictly more attractive than B. We note that, by (1) and the assumption that Jane is Bayesian, this can happen only if j 2 B, but j 2 = A. Intuitively, the only di¤erence between Jane’s preferences before 5

and after lunch is that after lunch she no longer cares whether the place she goes has orange juice or not. So, if her before lunch preference relation values menu B more than her after lunch relation, it has to be because B o¤ers exactly the alternative that loses its value once Jane learns she will not have to drive that evening. Following the insight provided by this example, we investigate in this paper the Bayesian updating behavior when the state-space of the model is subjective. We work in the setup of Dekel et al. (2001) –henceforth DLR–and our main condition is a generalization of the idea discussed in the previous paragraph. In words, our condition says that if menus A and B are such that A 2 B, but B %1 A, then it must be the case that %1 sees some gain in ‡exibility when moving from menu A to menu A [ B that %2 does not see. In our example, this corresponds to the fact that %1 considers it worthwhile to have the option j in menu B, while for %2 this is entirely irrelevant. When %1 and %2 satisfy this condition, we say that %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 . The upshot of the present paper is that this condition is intrinsically related to the possibility of representing %2 as a Bayesian update of %1 ’s representation. If the state-space used in the representation of %1 is …nite, we show that this connection is tight, that is, being a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 is necessary and su¢ cient to make %2 representable by a Bayesian update of %1 ’s representation. Without the …niteness of the state-space used in %1 ’s representation, an additional technical condition is necessary in order to obtain a similar result. In more abstract terms, this paper can be also seen as relating a comparative theory of preference for ‡exibility to Bayesian updating. DLR show that for a pair of relations %1 and %2 that can be represented as in (1), if %1 values ‡exibility more than %2 , then the state-space used in the representation of %1 is larger than the one used in the representation of %2 . We discuss this result formally in Section 3 bellow, but it is worth noting here that the results in this paper may be seen in the garb of an extension of that analysis. Basically, our “less ‡exibility loving version” condition may be interpreted as saying that %1 values ‡exibility more than %2 and, in some sense, this is the only di¤erence between this two relations. In terms of the literature, the results here are related to two groups of papers. First, they can be seen as contributing to the extensive literature on updating. Of course, it departs from the tradition, since most of that literature works in a standard Savagean setup with an exogenously given state-space.1 1

See Epstein and Le Breton (1993), Ghirardato (2002) and the references therein, for a discus-

6

On the other hand this paper is related to the preferences over menus literature.2 This literature had an increase in popularity after the works of DLR and Gul and Pesendorfer (2001). In that literature, however, only a few papers have performed exercises similar to the one performed here, by way of studying how some comparative notion relating a pair of menu preferences a¤ects the properties of a given model. For example, Gul and Pesendorfer (2001) show that a self-control preference %1 has more self-control than another such preference %2 if and only if %2 ’s temptation ranking is closer to her “temptation free preference”than %1 ’s. In a similar fashion Sarver (2008) links two di¤erent measures of regret attitudes to interesting properties of his regret representation. The remainder of our paper is organized as follows. We discuss the primitives of the model and revisit some results of DLR, Dekel, Lipman, Rustichini, and Sarver (2007) –henceforth DLRS– and Dekel, Lipman, and Rustichini (2008) –henceforth DLR2–in Section 2. In Section 3, we present the comparative theory of preference for ‡exibility that will be later related to Bayesian updating. In particular, we de…ne the fundamental notion of a less ‡exibility loving version. Next, in Section 4, we prove our …rst result relating the notion of a less ‡exibility loving version to Bayesian updating in the …nite state-space case. Section 5 extends the analysis in Section 4 to the case of an in…nite state-space. The Bayesian updating result found in Section 5 characterizes Bayesian updating only when the observed event satis…es a certain topological condition. For completeness, we give a general characterization of Bayesian updating in Section 6, but for that we have to pay the cost of working with further technical conditions. Section 7 concludes. We relegate most of the proofs to the appendix.

2

Preference for Flexibility and Additive EU Representations

In this section we brie‡y revisit some results from DLR and DLRS that we shall need for our subsequent analysis. We …rst describe the primitives of their model. Let X be a …nite set of alternatives and (X) the space of lotteries (probability distributions) on X. We view (X) as a metric subspace of RjXj and represent its sion of Bayesian updating in the classic Savagean framework. For a discussion of non-Bayesian updating rules, see Epstein (2006) and Epstein, Noor, and Sandroni (2008). On updating in the context of the multiple priors model of Gilboa and Schmeidler (1989), see Epstein and Schneider (2003), Gilboa and Schmeidler (1993), Hanany and Klibano¤ (2007) and Siniscalchi (2006). 2 See Kreps (1979), Nehring (1999), Gul and Pesendorfer (2001) and DLR.

7

elements by p; q; r, etc..3 Let X represent the space of nonempty closed subsets of the relative interior of (X). That is, X is the set of all nonempty closed subsets of (X) that include only lotteries with full support. We consider binary relations % on X . As usual, we denote the symmetric part of % by and the asymmetric part by . The elements of X are represented by capital letters A; B; C; etc., and are called menus. The idea here is that an agent whose preference relation is % faces a two-period decision problem. In the …rst period she chooses a menu knowing that in the next period she will have to make a choice from that menu. Following DLR, we do not explicitly model the agent’s second period choice, leaving it as part of the interpretation of the results presented in this section. 2.1

Representations

The uncertainty of the agent about her future tastes is modeled by a probability measure over a set of possible ex post utility functions. As in DLR, we impose the restriction that each ex post utility function be of the expected utility type. Because expected utility functions are only unique up to positive a¢ ne transformations, it is convenient to impose a normalization on the set of ex post utility functions we use in our representations. Consequently, we de…ne the set of normalized expected utility functions on (X) as 8 9 jXj jXj < = X X U := u 2 RjXj : ui = 0 and u2i = 1 : : ; i=1

Just like

i=1

(X), we view U as a metric subspace of RjXj .

We are now ready to introduce the concept of a Positive Additive Expected Utility representation that will be extensively used in this paper. De…nition. We say that a binary relation % on X has a Positive Additive Expected Utility (PAEU) representation, , if is a Borel probability measure on U such that the function W : X ! R, which is de…ned by W (A) := 3

Z

max Ep (u) (ds) ;

U p2A

Since X is …nite, this is equivalent to endow

8

(X) with the topology of weak convergence.

represents % :4 In what follows we shall also have the opportunity to consider PAEU representations in which only a …nite number of states are relevant for the agent’s decisions: De…nition. We say that a binary relation % on X has a …nite PAEU representation, , if is a PAEU representation of % with …nite support. 2.2

Axioms and Representation Theorems

We now present the postulates that characterize when a binary relation % on X admits a PAEU or a …nite PAEU representation. Axiom 1 (Preorder). % is a complete preorder on X . Axiom 2 (vNM Continuity). For any menus A; B; C with A two numbers, and in (0; 1) such that A

C

B

A

B

C, there exist

C:5

Axiom 3 (Independence). For any two menus A and B; A for any

B implies A

C

B

C;

2 (0; 1] and C 2 X :

Axiom 4 (Nontriviality). There exist two menus A and B such that A

B:

These properties are extensively discussed in DLR and DLRS, so we shall not elaborate on them here. In addition to these four postulates, here we will also work with the assumption that the binary relation % satis…es the monotonicity property introduced by Koopmans (1964). Axiom 5 (Monotonicity). For any two menus A and B; B

A implies A % B:

4

Here Ep (u) represents the expectation of the random variable on RjXj that takes value ui with probability pi , i = 1; :::; jXj : 5 Notation: For any two menus A; B and 2 [0; 1] , by A B we mean the set fp 2 (X) : p = q + (1 ) r for some q 2 A and r 2 Bg :

9

This property is what Kreps (1979) refers to as preference for ‡exibility. The interpretation comes from the idea that the agent chooses today a menu from which she will have to make a choice tomorrow. With regards to this interpretation, the Monotonicity axiom says that the agent always likes the ‡exibility of having more options to choose from in the future. In their seminal contributions, DLR and DLRS prove that an individual whose preference relation on X abides by the above …ve postulates is guaranteed to have a PAEU representation. Theorem 1 (DLRS). A binary relation % on X satis…es Preorder, vNM Continuity, Independence, Nontriviality and Monotonicity if and only if it has a unique PAEU representation.6 Motivated by this result, we call % a PAEU preference whenever it satis…es Preorder, vNM Continuity, Independence, Nontriviality and Monotonicity. Some of the results in this paper will be derived under the assumption that % has, in fact, a …nite PAEU representation. The following condition, found by DLR2, characterizes this case. Axiom 6 (Finiteness). Every menu A has a …nite subset C such that A

C.

This property is powerful enough to guarantee that a PAEU preference admits a …nite PAEU representation. Theorem 2 (DLR2). A binary relation % on X satis…es Preorder, vNM Continuity, Independence, Nontriviality, Monotonicity and Finiteness if and only if it has a unique …nite PAEU representation. Throughout the present paper we refer to a binary relation on X that satis…es the six postulates in the statement of Theorem 2 as a …nite PAEU preference.

3

Comparative Desire for Flexibility

In this section we discuss some comparative notions of desire for ‡exibility. We begin with the following de…nition due to DLR. 6

Actually, DLRS do not state this result in terms of the normalized space U as we do here. Instead, they write it in terms of a generic measurable space and a generic state-dependent utility function. As it is clear from the proof in their paper, however, a binary relation % on X has a representation in terms of generic measurable state and state-dependent utility function if and only if it has a representation in terms of the normalized state-space used here.

10

De…nition. We say that a binary relation %1 on X values ‡exibility more than some other binary relation %2 on X if and only if, for any two menus A and B with B A; A 2 B implies A 1 B: In words, %1 values ‡exibility more than %2 if in any situation where %2 strictly prefers the ‡exibility of having more options, so does %1 . When %1 and %2 are PAEU preferences, one can show that this property has a rather intuitive characterization. Lemma 1. Suppose %1 and %2 are PAEU preferences with representations 2 , respectively. Then, %1 values ‡exibility more than %2 if and only if supp ( 2 )

1

and

supp ( 1 ) :7

This result says that %1 values ‡exibility more than %2 if and only if every future state considered possible by %2 is also considered possible by %1 . The “if” part of this fact is, of course, straightforward. We prove its “only if”in the Appendix, but, in passing, we note that the needed argument basically consists of showing that if supp ( 2 ) n supp ( 1 ) 6= ;, then it is possible to …nd two menus A and B with B A such that A 2 B, but A 1 B: In DLR we …nd a more general version of Lemma 1. First, instead of writing the result in terms of the normalized set U, they state it in terms of a generic state space and a suitable topology on the space of expected utility preferences on (X). Moreover, they show that the assertion is true for a class of binary relations larger than the class of PAEU preferences. The simpler version of the result stated here, however, will be enough for our purposes. Now, let A and B be any two menus such that A B. We want to be able to say that %1 values the ‡exibility provided by the extra options in B more than %2 . We are going to represent such a situation by the binary relation B de…ned below. De…nition. For any two menus A and B, we say that B B A, if and only if A and there exists a menu C such that A[C 7

2

B [ C, but A [ C

Notation: For a given probability measure

1

B [ C:

we use supp ( ) to represent the support of :

11

B

We call B the Extra-‡exibility relation and note that it is an asymmetric binary relation on X (The dependence of B on %1 and %2 is suppressed in our notation for simplicity.) In the de…nition above, the presence of the options in C makes the ‡exibility gained with the extra options in B worthless for %2 . However, %1 sees the opportunity of choosing from that larger menu in the future as a strict improvement. When %1 and %2 are PAEU preferences, the Extra-‡exibility relation has an interesting characterization. Lemma 2. Suppose %1 and %2 are preferences with PAEU representations 1 and 2 , respectively, and de…ne Si := supp ( i ) for i = 1; 2. For any two menus A and B such that A B, we have B B A if and only if there exists some u 2 S1 n S2 such that max Ep (u) > max Ep (u) : p2B

p2A

This result says that the existence of a situation where %2 does not see any gain in having the possibility of choosing from the larger menu, B, while %1 does, is equivalent to the existence of some state, considered possible only by %1 , at which it is strictly better to make a choice from B than from A: Above, we learned how to characterize when %1 values ‡exibility more than %2 . That de…nition is valid even if the di¤erences between %1 and %2 go far beyond the way they value ‡exibility. In some cases, it might be interesting to be able to say that the only di¤erence between %1 and %2 is the fact that %1 values ‡exibility more than %2 . One way to capture this idea is to require that any disagreement between %1 and %2 be only a consequence of %1 ’s higher desire for ‡exibility. The de…nition below formalizes this discussion. De…nition. We say that %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 if for any menus A and B; A 2 B and B %1 A imply A [ B B A: Thus, if %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 , and we have A 2 B, but B %1 A, then it must be the case that there exists at least one situation where %2 sees no value in adding the options in B to A, but %1 still sees that as a strict improvement. In this sense, whenever the two preferences disagree in the way described above, we can blame the disagreement on the fact that %1 sees more value in the ‡exibility achieved by adding B to A than %2 : 12

We note that if %1 and %2 are PAEU preferences and %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 , then, clearly, %1 values ‡exibility more than %2 . Intuitively, if B A, then neither %1 nor %2 see any gain in ‡exibility when B is added to A. Therefore, we will never be able to …nd a situation where %1 sees a strict gain in adding the options in B to A and %2 does not. But then, it is immediate from the assumption that %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 that A 1 B if A 2 B. We summarize this discussion with the following lemma: Lemma 3. Let %1 and %2 be two PAEU preferences. If %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 , then %1 values ‡exibility more than %2 . The next two sections will be dedicated to the characterization of the less ‡exibility loving versions of a given PAEU preference, %1 . We are going to see that if %1 is a …nite PAEU preference, then they correspond exactly to the preferences which can be represented as a Bayesian update of the representation of %1 . When %1 does not have a PAEU representation with a …nite support an additional condition will be needed in order to obtain a similar result.

4

Finite PAEU Preferences and Bayesian Updating

In the previous section we introduced the notion of a less ‡exibility loving version of a given PAEU preference %1 . That property captured the idea of a relation di¤ering from %1 only because of its weaker desire for ‡exibility. We now show that when %1 has a representation with a …nite support, its less ‡exibility loving versions correspond exactly to the relations that can be obtained as a Bayesian update of %1 ’s representation. The formal result is the following: Theorem 3. Let %1 be a …nite PAEU preference. A PAEU preference %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 if and only if there exists a Borel subset T of U such that the PAEU representation, 2 , of %2 is the Bayesian update of the PAEU representation, 1 , of %1 after the observation of T: The intuition for the result above is simple. Suppose …rst that the representation, 2 , of %2 is a Bayesian update of the representation, 1 , of %1 . Let Si := supp ( i ),

13

for i = 1; 2. It is easy to see that this implies that, for any two menus A and B; X

2

X

1 (u) max Ep (u)

(u) max Ep (u) p2A

u2S2

() p2A

u2S2

X

2

(u) max Ep (u)

X

1

(u) max Ep (u) :

p2B

u2S2

p2B

u2S2

So, if A 2 B and B %1 A for some pair of menus A and B, it must be the case that there exists u 2 S1 n S2 such that max Ep (u ) > max Ep (u ) : p2B

p2A

By Lemma 2, we know that this implies that A [ B B A. We conclude that %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 . Conversely, suppose that the representation, 2 , of %2 is not a Bayesian update of the representation, 1 , of %1 . In the appendix we show that in this case we can always …nd two menus A and B such that X

2 (u) max Ep (u) > p2A

u2S2

but

X

u2S1

1

X

2

(u) max Ep (u) ;

u2S2

X

(u) max Ep (u) p2A

u2S1

1

p2B

(u) max Ep (u) p2B

and max Ep (u) p2A

max Ep (u) for all u 2 S1 n S2 : p2B

Again, by Lemma 2, this implies that A [ B B A is false and, therefore, %2 is not a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 . In brief, the proof of Theorem 3 consists of showing that if it is not the case that the representation of %2 is a Bayesian update of the representation of %1 , then we can always …nd two menus A and B such that %1 and %2 disagree about the ranking of these two menus, but the reason for that is not %1 ’s stronger desire for ‡exibility. This makes the behavioral implications of the Bayesian updating result in Theorem 3 intuitive and easy to understand. The tight connection between the concept of a less ‡exibility loving version and Bayesian updating for …nite PAEU preferences naturally makes one wonder if such a result remains true when the …niteness assumption is dropped. Unfortunately, as Example 1 bellow shows, this is not the case. 14

u S2 S1 Figure 1 Example 1. Suppose jXj = 3. In this case U is simply a circle of radius one and center (0; 0; 0) located on the hyperplane that is parallel to the simplex and touches the origin. Let 1 be a prior over U whose support, S1 , is an arc of this circle (for simplicity we represent this arc as a line segment in Figure 1). We also assume that 1 has a unique mass point, u , located somewhere between the two extremities of the arc S1 . Now consider another prior, 2 , whose support, S2 , is an arc that goes from one of the extremities of the arc S1 to the point u (See Figure 1). Finally, we assume that 1 and 2 satisfy (V ) , for all V 1 (S2 n fu g)

(V ) = 2 (S2 n fu g)

1

2

and

(fu g) 1 = 2 2 (S2 n fu g) 2

S2 n fu g ;

(fu g) : 1 (S2 n fu g) 1

Now consider the PAEU preferences %1 and %2 induced by the priors 1 and 2 , and let A and B be any two menus such that A [ B B A is false. By Lemma 2, we know that this is equivalent to say that max Ep (u) for all u 2 S1 n S2 :

max Ep (u) p2A

p2B

It is not hard to see that this implies max Ep (u ) p2A

max Ep (u ) : p2B

But then, Z

max Ep (u) p2A

max Ep (u) p2B

1

Z

(du)

S1

S2

max Ep (u) p2A

Z

S2

15

max Ep (u) p2A

max Ep (u) p2B

max Ep (u) p2B

1 (du)

2 (du);

Less Flexibility Loving Version

-

Finite State-space

Bayesian Updating

6

6

Theorem 4

Theorem 6

?

?

?

??

Figure 2 where := It is now clear that if A

2

B, which is equivalent to say that

Z

max Ep (u)

max Ep (u)

2

(du) > 0;

Z

max Ep (u)

max Ep (u)

1

(du) > 0;

p2A

S2

then

(S2 n fu g) : 2 (S2 n fu g) 1

S1

which is equivalent to A %1 :

p2A 1

p2B

p2B

B. That is, %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of

Example 1 shows that being a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 is not enough to make %2 representable as a Bayesian update of %1 ’s representation when %1 does not necessarily satisfy Finiteness. This leaves us with two open questions, represented by the diagram in Figure 2. First of all, we may investigate the consequences of the less ‡exibility loving version concept when the …niteness assumption is dropped. This is the subject of Section 5, where we will see that although such a concept is not powerful enough to deliver a full Bayesian updating result in the in…nite state-space case, it is still related to some quasi-bayesian property linking the representations of %1 and %2 . Of course, alternatively, one could abandon the concept of a less ‡exibility loving version and simply focus on the characterization of Bayesian updating for generic PAEU preferences. We do that in Section 6. Unfortunately, the conditions that 16

deliver such a result are more technical and harder to interpret than the property of being a less ‡exibility loving version.

5

Less Flexibility Loving Versions of an In…nite PAEU Preference

We now characterize the less ‡exibility loving versions of a generic, not necessarily …nite, PAEU preference, %1 . Although it is no longer true that any less ‡exibility loving version, %2 , of %1 can be represented as a Bayesian update of %1 0 s representation, we will see that this property is still related to some quasi-bayesian behavior from the part of %2 . We …rst present the formal result and discuss it afterwards. Theorem 4. Suppose %1 and %2 have PAEU representations 1 and 2 , respectively. De…ne S1 := supp ( 1 ). Then, %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 if and only if there exists a closed subset, T , of S1 such that 2 (T ) = 1 and either intS1 (T ) = ; or, for any Borel subset V of U; (V ) 2 (intS1 (T )) 2

(V ) , with equality if V 1 (intS1 (T )) 1

intS1 (T ) :8

(2)

So, the theorem above says that if %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 , then we can …nd a closed subset, T , of the state-space used to represent %1 such that %2 ’s representation will act as a Bayesian update of %1 ’s representation in the interior of T . We note that if 2 were a Bayesian update of 1 after the observation of intS1 (T ), then, for events V 2 S1 n intS1 (T ) we would have 2 (V ) = 0. On the other hand, if 2 were a Bayesian update of 1 after the observation of T , then we would have (2) satis…ed with equality even for the events V T n intS1 (T ). So, for events in T n intS1 (T ), 2 assigns probabilities that lie in between what a Bayesian updater that had observed intS1 (T ) and what a Bayesian updater that had observed T would assign. We note that Example 1 can be perfectly mapped into the conditions in Theorem 4. If we de…ne T to be S2 in that example, then intS1 (T ) = S2 n fu g and it can be easily checked that condition (2) in Theorem 4 is satis…ed. In fact, Example 1 points out to the main reason why the concept of a less ‡exibility loving version does not imply a full Bayesian updating result when %1 is 8

Notation: By intS1 (T ) we mean the interior of T relative to the metric subspace S1 .

17

not a …nite PAEU preference. This is a consequence of the continuity of max Ep (:) ; p2A

when viewed as a function from U to R, for any menu A. Because of that, whenever we have two menus A and B such that A [ B B A is false, which, by Lemma 2, is equivalent to max Ep (u) max Ep (u) for all u 2 S1 n S2 ; p2A

p2B

we in fact have max Ep (u) p2A

max Ep (u) for all u 2 cl (S1 n S2 ) :9 p2B

We can now see that if 2 acts as a Bayesian update of 1 inside intS1 (S2 ), we are no longer capable of …nding two menus A and B that contradict the fact that %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 the same way we did in the proof of Theorem 3. We now discuss a possible way to strengthen Theorem 4 to a full Bayesian updating result. The idea here will be to impose a condition that guarantees that the left-hand side of (2) is null whenever V U n intS1 (T ). It turns out that this is related to a sort of independence condition between the relations %2 and B. Formally, we consider the following property: De…nition. For any two PAEU preferences, %1 and %2 , we say that %2 is strongly independent from B if and only if for any two menus A and B, A 2 B implies that there exists a set D 2 X [ f;g such that A

2

B [ D, but A [ B [ D B B [ D is false.

Loosely speaking, the condition above says that it can never be the case that the reason for %2 to prefer a menu A to a menu B is the extra ‡exibility that %1 sees in A, when compared to %2 . The axiom presents a strong version of this idea. It asks that whenever %2 strictly prefers a menu A to a menu B, it must be possible to add options to menu B in a way that it eliminates any extra ‡exibility %1 might see in A, but it still does not reverse %2 ’s preference. It turns out that this postulate is too strong for our objectives, so we need to weaken it by instead of asking the above to be immediately true, we allow …rst for the mixing of A and B with some other menu 9

Notation: For any set T , by cl (T ) we mean the closure of T:

18

C. Formally, we work with the following weaker version of the de…nition above: De…nition. For any two PAEU preferences, %1 and %2 , we say that %2 is independent from B if and only if for any two menus A and B, A 2 B implies that there exist menus C and D and number 2 [0; 1) such that C

A

2

(C

B) [ D, but [C

(A [ B)] [ D B (C

B) [ D is false.

Given the representations of %1 and %2 , we have that for any menu C and 2 [0; 1) ; A %i B () C A %i (C B) for i = 1; 2: So, this new condition, besides being a genuine weakening of the previous one, still carries the same interpretation. As we have pointed out before, when added to the requirement that %2 be a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 , the condition above delivers a Bayesian updating result in the spirit of Theorem 3. Theorem 5. Suppose %1 and %2 have PAEU representations 1 and 2 , respectively, and let S1 := supp ( 1 ). Then %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 that is independent from B if and only if there exists a set T that is regularly open in the subspace S1 such that 2 is the Bayesian update of 1 after the observation of T:10 In the appendix (Lemma 7) we prove that %2 is independent from B if and only if 11 If S2 S1 , this is equivalent to say that 2 (intS1 (S2 )) = 2 (S2 \ cl (S1 n S2 )) = 0. 1. The theorem above is, therefore, an easy corollary of this fact and Theorem 4. Theorem 5 uses an auxiliary condition to relate the concept of a less ‡exibility loving version to a particular Bayesian updating result relating two PAEU preferences. It leaves open the question about which condition, if any, would generically characterize Bayesian updating. In the next section we provide such a condition. Unfortunately, that condition is more technical and far less intuitive than the property of being a less ‡exibility loving version.

6

In…nite PAEU Preferences and Bayesian Updating

So far, our main goal has been to characterize the less ‡exibility loving versions of a given PAEU preference, %1 . We now depart from that goal and, instead, aim at 10 11

Given a topological space Z, a subset O of Z is regularly open if and only if O = int (cl (O)) : In the language of Example 1 this means simply 2 (fu g) = 0:

19

…nding a condition that generically characterizes when a PAEU preference %2 can be represented as a Bayesian update of the PAEU representation of %1 . We begin with a de…nition. De…nition. Consider a PAEU preference, %. We say that a pair of menus C and D preserve % in the limit if, for any two menus A and B with A B, there exists 2 (0; 1) such that C for all

2

A [ [D

(A [ B)]

B) [ [D

(C

(A [ B)] ;

;1 :

Note that, for any

2 (0; 1) ; A

B () C

A

C

B;

but, of course, the addition of the term [D (A [ B)] could, in general, reverse the preference above. The de…nition above says that C and D preserve % in the limit if the term [D (A [ B)] is always inconsequential when is large enough. We now use the de…nition above to write the condition that generically characterizes Bayesian updating in the present setting. De…nition. For a pair of PAEU preferences, %1 and %2 , we say that %2 can be extracted from %1 if for any pair of menus A and B with A 2 B we can …nd a number 2 (0; 1) and menus C and D that preserve %2 in the limit such that (C for all

2

A) [ [D

(A [ B)]

1

(C

B) [ [D

(A [ B)] ;

(3)

;1 :

As we have already mentioned, this condition gives a general characterization of Bayesian updating for PAEU preferences. Theorem 6. Suppose %1 and %2 have PAEU representations 1 and 2 , respectively. Then %2 can be extracted from %1 if and only if there exists a Borel subset T of supp ( 1 ) such that either 1 (T ) = 0 and 2 (T ) = 1 or 2 is the Bayesian update of 1 after the observation of T: The interpretation of Theorem 6 is simple. Whenever %2 can be extracted from %1 , we can represent %2 as being an instance of %1 after having learned that the 20

event T occurred. If %1 assigns probability zero to the event T , then the theorem does not impose any restriction on %2 ’s beliefs over T . However, whenever 1 (T ) > 0 and, therefore, Bayesian updating is well-de…ned, %2 makes use of the Baye’s rule to update 1 : 7

Conclusion

We studied updating in the absence of an exogenously speci…ed state-space. We worked in the framework of Dekel et al. (2001), where the state-space is endogenously obtained as part of the representation of a preference relation over menus. In that environment, we proved results that connected Bayesian updating to a comparative theory of preference for ‡exibility. The analysis in this paper is essentially static, so a natural way to extend the results here is to embed them in a truly dynamic model. Also, we only work with the model that can be considered to be the correspondent, in the preference over menus literature, to the standard subjective expected utility model in a Savagean world. The same way the updating theory is extended to other models when the statespace is exogenously given, it would also be interesting to see which implications the conditions here would have for some of the alternative models that have been studied in the preferences over menus literature.12

A A.1

Proofs Preliminaries

In this section we collect a series of results that will be useful for the proof of the theorems in the main text. As we did in the main text, de…ne 0

U := @u 2 RjXj :

jXj X i=1

For any menu A, the support function A

ui = 0 and

jXj X i=1

A

1

u2i = 1A :

: U ! R is de…ned by

(u) := max Ep (u) , for each u 2 U. p2A

12

A natural candidate would be the menu preferences version of the maxmim model proved by Epstein, Marinacci, and Seo (2007).

21

It is easy to show that the map that associates to each menu its support function is injective. If % has a PAEU representation with prior , then, for any two menus A and B; Z Z A % B ()

A

(u) (du)

B

U

(u) (du) :

U

The following lemma collect some standard results about support functions: Lemma 4. For any two menus A and B, the following conditions are satis…ed:13 1. 2.

A+(1

A[B

=

)B

=

A

_

A B;

+ (1

)

B

for any

2 [0; 1] ;

14

3. dHausdorf f (A; B) = dSupnorm (

A;

B) :

Now, let C (U) be the space of continuous functions over U endowed with the supnorm distance. It is well known that C := f

A

: A is a menug

C (U) :

We are also going to work with the following subsets of C (U) : H :=

S

rC

r 0

and H := H

H:

DLR prove that H satis…es the following properties: Lemma 5. H satis…es the following conditions: 1. H is a linear subspace of C (U) ; 2. For any f 2 H , there exists r > 0 and

1;

2

2 C such that f = r (

1

2) ;

3. The set H is dense in C (U) : 13

All properties can be easily checked from the de…nition of a support function. The …rst two can be found in Rockafellar (1997), chapter 13. 14 That is, for any u 2 U, A[B (u) = max f A (u) ; B (u)g :

22

A.2

A Useful Lemma

Let C and D be any two menus and let % be a preference that has a PAEU representation with probability measure . De…ne a set T U by T := fu 2 U :

(u) >

C

D

(u)g .

We can prove that: Lemma 6. For any two menus A and B, de…ne f :=

(C

A)[[D

(A[B)]

(C

B)[[D

(A[B)]

and f^ :=

(C

It must be the case that Z Z 1 f (u) (du) = ( lim "1 1 U T

A)

A

B)[[D

(C

B ) (u)

(A[B)] :

1

(du) = lim

1

"1

Z

f^ (u) (du) :

T

To prove the lemma, …rst note that for any ; Z

f (u) (du) =

Z

f (u) (du) :

T

U

Now let " > 0 and pick any closed subset T" of T such that need the following claim: Claim 1. There exists D

2 (0; 1) such that for any (A[B)

(u) < min f

C

A

(u) ;

2 C

(T n T" ) < "=2.15 We

; 1 and any u 2 T" ; B

(u)g :

Proof of Claim. Since T" is a compact set and C and D are continuous functions that satisfy C (u) > D (u) for any u 2 T" , we know that there exists > 0 such that C (u) > D (u) + ; for all u 2 T" . Now note that for any two menus A and B and any u 2 U, 15 Since is a Borel probability measure over the metric space U it is regular, so we can always …nd such a set T" :

23

j

A

(u)

D

B

(A[B)

2. So if we make

(u)j

(u) =

D


0 small enough.

25

for some p 2 int ( (X))

and A := E.17 It is easy to see that A (u) = B (u) for all u 2 S1 , which implies that B 1 A. On the other hand, B (u) < A (u) for all u 2 S2 n S1 . This implies that B 2 A and, therefore, it is not true that %1 values ‡exibility more than %2 . A.4

Proof of Lemma 2

Suppose that there exists u 2 S1 n S2 with for any u; v 2 U and p 2 (X) ; jEp (u)

B

Ep (v)j

(u ) >

d (u; v) :

A

(u ). We …rst note that

(4)

We can now prove the following claim: Claim 1. Let ~" := ( B (u ) u 2 U satisfying d (u; u )

(u )) =4. There exists 0 < < 2 such that for any we can …nd qu 2 (X) with A

Equ (u )
A (u) for any u such that d (u; u ) 1 . De…ne := min f 1 ; ~"g. For any u such that d ( u; u ) , pick qu 2 arg max Eq (u) . q2 (X)

By construction we have Equ (u)

A

( u) ;

which implies that Equ ( u) =

Equ (u)

< 17

A

( u)

B

(u )

2~":

Since E is a sphere, it is easy to see that each expected-utility function has a unique maximizer in E. Moreover, no q 2 E maximizes two di¤erent expected-utility functions in U:

26

By (4) we have jEqu ( u)

Equ (u )j

d ( u; u )

~":

Combining the two conditions above we get Equ (u ) < Since obviously Equ (u)

B

B

(u )

~":

(u), this completes the proof of the claim.

k

Now consider the following set T := fu 2 S2 :

B

(u) >

A

(u)g :

We also need the following claim: Claim 2. There exists ^" > 0 such that for any u 2 T such that d ( u; u ) > , where the here is the one found in the claim above, there exists qu 2 int ( (X)) with the property that Equ (u ) < B (u ) ^" and Equ (u)

B

(u) :

Proof of Claim. Since B int ( (X)), we know that there exists 1 > 0 such that for any p 2 B and any point r 2 af f ( (X)) with (d (p; r))2 1 necessarily has to be in int ( (X)).18 Moreover, since u 2 S1 n S2 , there exists 0 < 2 < 2 such that for any u 2 S2 , d (u; u ) > 2 ; or, equivalently,

Now observe that d ( u; u ) >

2 2

: 2 is equivalent to say that u u 2

(u u )
0 such that for any u 2 T , there exists qu 2 the property that Equ (u ) < B (u ) "

(X) with

and Equ (u)

B

(u) :

Now …x " satisfying the condition in the claim above. For each u 2 T pick some qu 2 (X) such that Equ (u ) < B (u ) " and Equ (u) B (u). From the argument used in the proof of the previous claim we see that we can, in fact, choose such lotteries qu ’s in a way that they be uniformly distanced away from the boundary of the simplex. De…ne C to be the closure of the set of all qu ’s found this way. By what we have just discussed, C int ( (X)). It is now clear that for all u 2 S2 we must have A[C (u) = A[B[C (u) ; 28

and this implies that A [ C construction, that

2

A[C

which implies that A [ C

1

A [ B [ C. On the other hand, we have, by (u )
A (u ) : By Lemma 2, we know that this implies that B B A: [Su¢ ciency] Let 1 be the prior used in representation of %1 and 2 be the one used in the representation of %2 . By Lemmas 1 and 3, we know that supp ( 2 ) =: S2 S1 := supp ( 1 ). Suppose, then, that 2 is not the Bayesian updating of 1 after the observation of S2 . By a separation argument we can show that this implies that there exists f 2 C (U) such that X

2 (u) f (u) > 0 >

u2S2

X

1

(u) f (u) :

u2S2

Moreover, we can …nd such a function f that in addition to the above also satis…es: X

1

(u) f (u) < 0

u2S1

and f (u) = " for all u 2 S1 n S2 where " > 0.19 But then, Lemma 5 implies that 19

For the details about how to …nd such a function, see the argument in the proof of Theorem 4. Alternatively, one can derive this direction of the proof as a straightforward corollary of that

29

there exist menus A and B such that X

2

(u)

A

(u) >

u2S2

X

X

2

(u)

B

(u) ;

u2S2

1

(u)

A

(u)
B (u) for all u 2 S1 n S2 . The conditions above imply that A 2 B, B 1 A. But now notice that for any menu C such that A [ C 2 A [ B [ C, we must necessarily have A[C (u) B[C (u) for all u 2 S2 . Since A (u) > B (u) for all u 2 S1 n S2 , it must be the case that A[C (u) B[C (u) for all u 2 S1 , which implies that A [ C 1 A [ B [ C. This contradicts the fact that %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 . We conclude that 2 must be the Bayesian update of 1 after the observation of S2 : A.6

Proof of Theorem 4

[Necessity] Suppose %1 ; %2 have representations 1 ; 2 that satisfy the conditions in the statement of the theorem and let Si := supp ( i ) for i = 1; 2. It is easy to see that S2 = T and intS1 (T ) = S2 n cl (S1 n S2 ). Now pick any two menus A and B such that A 2 B and B %1 A. Suppose …rst that S2 cl (S1 n S2 ). Since A 2 B and B %1 A, there must exist u 2 S1 such that B (u) > A (u). If u 2 = S1 n S2 , then u 2 S2 cl (S1 n S2 ). But then, for u 2 S1 n S2 su¢ ciently close to u it must still be true that B (u ) > A (u ). By Lemma 2, this implies that A [ B B A. Now assume that S2 ncl (S1 n S2 ) 6= ; and suppose that A (u) B (u) for all u 2 S1 nS2 . Since support functions are continuous, this implies that B

(u)

A

(u)

for all u 2 cl (S1 n S2 ) as well. We can now show that our representation implies that Z Z 1 (S2 n cl(S1 n S2 )) ( A ( A B )(u) 2 (du): B )(u) 1 (du) 2 (S2 n cl(S1 n S2 )) S2 \cl(S1 nS2 )

S2 \cl(S1 nS2 )

To see that, let f m be an increasing sequence of non-negative simple functions over S2 \ cl (S1 n S2 ) converging to the restriction of A B to S2 \ cl (S1 n S2 ). But for Theorem.

30

any simple function f m , Z

f m (u)

X

1 (du) =

c

1

(f m )

1

(c)

c2f m (S2 \cl(S1 nS2 ))

S2 \cl(S1 nS2 )

X (S2 n cl (S1 n S2 )) 2 (S2 n cl (S1 n S2 )) c2f m (S \cl(S nS )) 2 1 2 Z f m (u) 2 (du) ; 1

=

2

(f m )

1

(c)

S2 \cl(S1 nS2 )

where (f m )

1

(c) := fu 2 S2 \ cl (S1 n S2 ) : f m (u) = cg :

An application of the monotone convergence theorem shows that Z

(

A

B )(u) 1 (du)

S2 \cl(S1 nS2 )

But then Z ( A S1

B ) (u)

1

n cl(S1 n S2 )) 2 (S2 n cl(S1 n S2 ))

Z

1 (S2

Z

(du)

(

A

B )(u) 2 (du):

S2 \cl(S1 nS2 )

B ) (u)

A

(

1

(du)

S2 ncl(S1 nS2 )

+

Z

(

A

S2 \cl(S1 nS2 )

(S2 n cl (S1 n S2 )) 2 (S2 n cl (S1 n S2 )) > 0; 1

B ) (u)

Z

(

1

A

(du)

B ) (u)

2

(du)

S2

where the …rst line uses the fact that A B is nonnegative in S1 nS2 and the second uses what we have just proved together with the representation. But this contradicts the assumption that B %1 A: We conclude that there must exist u 2 S1 n S2 with B (u ) > A (u ) and, by Lemma 2 again, we know that this implies that A[B B A: [Su¢ ciency] Now suppose that %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 and let 1 and 2 be their PAEU representations. By Lemmas 1 and 3 we know that supp ( 2 ) =: S2 S1 := supp ( 1 ). Suppose that S2 n cl (S1 n S2 ) 6= ;. We can prove the following claim.

31

S2o := S2 n cl (S1 n S2 ) ;

Claim 1. For any Borel set V

2

(V ) : o 1 (S2 ) 1

(V ) =

Proof of Claim. De…ne the auxiliary measure ~ 2 by ~ 2 (V ) =

1

(S2o )

2

(V ) , for any Borel set V

U:

Clearly, the claim is equivalent to say that ~ 2 (V ) = 1 (V ) whenever V S2o . Suppose this is not true. By a separation argument we can …nd a function f 2 C (U) such that Z Z f (u) 1 (du) > f (u) ~ 2 (du) : S2o

S2o

We can assume without loss of generality that Z

f (u)

S2o

Let

1

(du) > 0 >

> 0 be such that jf (u)j < Oi :=

Z

S2o

f (u) ~ 2 (du) :

for any u 2 U. For each i 2 N consider the sets

u 2 U : d (u; cl (S1 n S2 ))


U

~ := h Let h

Z

h (u) ~ 2 (du) :

U

" for some " > 0 such that it is still true that Z Z (h (u) ") 1 (du) > 0 > (h (u) ") ~ 2 (du) : U

U

33

~ to …nd h 2 H such that h (u) < 0 for Since H is dense in C (U), we can use h all u 2 cl (S1 n S2 ) and Z

h (u)

1

(du) > 0 >

U

Z

This implies that there exist menus A; B 2 2 Z

(

B

h (u) ~ 2 (du) :

U

A ) (u)

1

(du) > 0 >

U

(X)

Z

(

n f;g such that B

A ) (u)

~ 2 (du) ;

U

and A (u) > B (u) for all u 2 cl (S1 n S2 ). Of course, the condition above implies that B 1 A and A 2 B. By Lemma 2, this implies that B 7 A, which contradicts the fact that %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 . We conclude that 1 (V ) = k ~ 2 (V ) for any V S2o : To complete the proof of the theorem we need one last claim. Claim 2. For any Borel subset V of U; (V ) : o 1 (S2 )

(V ) o 2 (S2 )

1

2

Proof of Claim. Suppose that there exists Borel set V (V ) > o 2 (S2 ) 2

U with

(V ) : o 1 (S2 ) 1

De…ne ~ 2 as in the previous claim. The condition above is equivalent to ~ 2 (V ) > 1 (V ). Since 1 and ~ 2 are positive Borel measures over the metric space U and, therefore, are regular, we can assume without loss of generality that V is closed. De…ne := (~ 2 (V ) 1 (V )) =2 and let OV be some open subset of U such that V OV and 1 (OV n V ) < . By the Urysohn’s Lemma, there exists a continuous function f : S ! [ ; 1] such that f (u) = 1 for all u 2 V and f (u) = for all

34

u 2 U n OV . This implies that Z

U

Z

f (u) ~ 2 (du)

f (u) ~ 2 (du)

V

= ~ 2 (V ) =

Z1

>

(V ) + 2 f (u)

1

(du) +

V

Z

=

1

1

(du) +

OV nV

f (u)

1

(du) +

V

Z

Z

Z

Z

f (u)

1

(du) +

OV nV

f (u)

1

1

(du)

U nOV

Z

f (u)

1

(du)

U nOV

(du) :

U

R R Let " := U f (u) ~ 2 (du) f (u) 1 (du) . Now let F be any closed set in S2 n U cl (S1 n S2 ) with 1 (F ) > 0 and let OF be an open subset of U such that R

U

f (u)

(du) + "=2 1;2 (F ) 1

1;2

(OF n F ) < "=2;

and F

OF

U n cl (S1 n S2 ) :20

Again, we can make use of Urysohn’s Lemma to …nd a continuous function g : R f (u) 1 (du) + "=2 = 1;2 (F ) ; 0 such that, for any u 2 F , g (u) = U ! U R f (u) 1 (du) + "=2 = 1;2 (F ) and, for any u 2 U n OF , g (u) = 0. Now observe U that Z Z Z f (u) 1 (du) + "=2 = 1;2 (F ) ~ 2 (du) g (u) ~ 2 (du) U OF U Z = f (u) 1 (du) + "=2 = 1;2 (F ) 1;2 (OF ) U Z = f (u) 1 (du) + "=2 = 1;2 (F ) ( 1;2 (F ) + 1;2 (OF n F )) U Z > f (u) 1 (du) + "=2 "=2 U Z = f (u) 1 (du) " U Z = f (u) ~ 2 (du) : U

20

Notation: We write 1;2 (F ) and 1;2 (OF n F ) to indicate that This is a consequence of the previous claim.

35

1

and ~ 2 agree for this sets.

and Z

g (u)

1

Z

(du)

Z

F

U

=

Z

f (u)

1

(du) + "=2 =

(F )

1;2

1

(du)

U

f (u)

1

(du)

"=2:

U

But then Z

Z

(f + g) (u) ~ 2 (du) =

U

f (u) ~ 2 (du) +

ZU

>

Z

g (u) ~ 2 (du)

ZU

f (u) ~ 2 (du)

U

f (u) ~ 2 (du)

U

= 0; and Z

(f + g) (u)

1

(du) =

U

=

Z

f (u)

ZU

f (u)

1

1

(du) +

Z

ZU

(du)

g (u)

1

(du)

f (u)

1

(du)

"=2

U

U

"=2:

De…ne h := f + g and observe that h (u) = f (u) , for all u 2 cl (S1 n S2 ). By Lemma 5, we know that this implies the existence of menus A; B such that Z

(

A

B ) (u)

~ 2 (du) > 0 >

Z

(

A

B ) (u)

1

(du)

U

U

and A (u) > B (u) for all u 2 cl (S1 n S2 ). But the conditions above imply that A 2 B, B 1 A and A [ B 7 A, which contradicts the fact that %2 is a less ‡exibility loving version of %1 . We conclude that we must have ~ 2 (V ) 1 (V ) for all Borel subsets V of U: k Making T := S2 and using the two claims above concludes the proof of the theorem. A.7

Proof of Theorem 5

The theorem will be a consequence of the following lemma: Lemma 7. Let %1 ; %2 be PAEU preferences with representations 1 ; 2 and de…ne Si := supp ( i ), i = 1; 2. Then, %2 is independent from B if and only if 36

2

(cl (S1 n S2 )) = 0:

Proof of Lemma. Suppose 2 (cl (S1 n S2 )) = 0 and let A and B be two menus such that A 2 B. Let C be any closed sphere in the interior of (X) and de…ne S

D :=

arg max Ep (u) : p2C

u2cl(S1 nS2 )

We note that, by construction, fu 2 U : C (u) > D (u)g = Uncl (S1 n S2 ). For each 2 (0; 1), de…ne f^ := (C A) (C B)[[D (A[B)] . By Lemma 6, we know that Z Z 1 ^ f (u) 2 (du) = ( A lim B ) (u) 2 (du) : "1 1 Uncl(S1 nS2 ) U ncl(S1 nS2 ) Since

2

(cl (S1 n S2 )) = 0, the condition above implies that lim "1

1 1

Z

f^ (u)

(du) =

2

Z

(

B ) (u)

A

2

(du) > 0:

U

Uncl(S1 nS2 )

So, for su¢ ciently close to one, we have C A 2 (C B) [ [D (A [ B)]. Since obviously (C B)[[D (A[B)] (u) (C A) (u) for all u 2 cl (S1 n S2 ), we also have that [C (A [ B)] [ [D (A [ B)] 7 (C B) [ [D (A [ B)].21 We conclude that %2 is indeed independent from B : Conversely, suppose now that 2 (cl (S1 n S2 )) > 0. Now pick any " > 0 such that " 2 (S2 n cl (S1 n S2 )) < 2 (cl (S1 n S2 ) \ S2 ). Now pick a closed subset T of S2 n cl (S1 n S2 ) such that 2

(S2 n cl (S1 n S2 ))

2

" 1+"

(T )

2

(S2 n cl (S1 n S2 )) :

We can now use Urysohn’s Lemma to …nd a continuous function f : U ! [ "; 1] such that f (u) = " for all u 2 T and f (u) = 1 for all u 2 S2 \ cl (S1 n S2 ). By construction we have Z f (u) 2 (du) 0; S2 ncl(S1 nS2 )

with equality only if S2

cl (S1 n S2 ), and Z

f (u)

2

(du) > 0:

S2

21

Note that cl (A) cl ([C (A [ B)] [ [D

int ( (X)) implies that cl (C (A [ B)] n (C B) [ [D (A [ B)])

37

A) cl (C

int ( (X)) A) :

and

We can now use Lemma 5 to …nd menus A and B such that Z ( A 0 B ) (u) 2 (du) S2 ncl(S1 nS2 )

and

Z

(

A

B ) (u)

2

(du) > 0:

S2

By Lemma 2, we know that for any menus C; D and (A [ B)] [ D 7 (C

[C we must necessarily have this implies that Z

(

(C

B)[D

(C

(C

B)[D

(u)

(C

B) [ D A)

(u) for all u 2 cl (S1 n S2 ). But

Z

A) )(u) 2 (du)

S2

2 (0; 1] such that

(

(C

B)[D

(

(C

B)

A) )(u) 2 (du)

(C

S2 ncl(S1 nS2 )

Z

(C

A) )(u) 2 (du)

S2 ncl(S1 nS2 )

=

Z

0:

(

B

A ) (u)

2

(du)

S2 ncl(S1 nS2 )

We conclude that %2 is not independent from B and this …nishes the proof of the lemma. k Now note that theorem 5 is a straightforward corollary of Theorem 4 and the lemma above. A.8

Proof of Theorem 6

The proof will make use of the following lemmas: Lemma 8. Let % be a PAEU preference with representation . If C; D preserve in the limit, then (f C > D g) = 1: Proof of Lemma. Suppose (f D := C g) > 0 and let T := f D C g and (T ). Find a closed subset S of f C > D g with (f C > D g) (S) < (S), (T ) where := 2 (f C > D g) . Now use Urysohn’s Lemma to …nd a continuous function

38

f :U[

; 1] such that f (u) = Z

for u 2 S and f (u) = 1 for u 2 T . Note that

f (u) (du) >

(T )

(f

=

(T )

(T ) 2

U

C

>

D g)

C

>

D g)

> 0; but Z

f

f (u) (du) < C > Dg

(S) + ( (f

(S))

< 0:

By lemma 5, we can …nd menus A and B such that Z

A

(u)

B

(u) (du) > 0;

U

but

Z

f

A

(u)

B

(u) (du) < 0:

C > Dg

By Lemma 6, the second inequality implies that (C B) [ [D (A [ B)] (C A) [ [D (A [ B)] when is large, while, by assumption, the …rst is equivalent to say that A B. This contradicts the assumption that C and D preserve % in the limit and, therefore, we conclude that we must have (f C > D g) = 1: k Lemma 9. Let ( ; ) be a measurable space and let 1 ; 2 be two probability measures over ( ; ). There exists S 2 such that 2 (S) = 1 and for any T S, 2 (T ) = 0 =) 1 (T ) = 0: Proof of Lemma. By the Lebesgue decomposition theorem, there exists signed measures ~ 1 ; ^ 1 such that 1 = ~ 1 + ^ 1 , ~ 1 T^

B

T^

(u)

1

(du) :

Proof of Claim. If 2 is the Bayesian update of 1 after the observation of T , then we can simply make T^ := T . Suppose, then, that 1 (T ) = 0 and 2 (T ) = 1. Since A 2 B, we know that that A (u ) > B (u ) for some u 2 T S1 . By continuity of support functions, we know that in fact we must have A (u) > B (u) for all u in some neighborhood of u . This implies that Z

f

(

B ) (u)

A

A > B g[T

De…ning T^ := f

A

1

(du) =

Z

f

> 0: >

Bg

(

B ) (u)

A

[ T completes the proof of the claim.

Now let T^ be as in the claim above. By regularity of 40

1

(du)

A> B g

1,

k

we can …nd an open

superset O of T^ such that Z

A

(u)

1

(du) >

O

Z

B

(u)

Now let E be any closed sphere in the interior of C := E and D :=

1

(du) :

O

(X). De…ne the following sets:

p 2 E : fpg = arg max Eq (u) for some u 2 UnO : q2E

By construction, f C > D g = O and, by Lemma 6, it must be the case that (C A) [ [D (A [ B)] 1 (C B) [ [D (A [ B)] when is large. Again, by Lemma 6, it is clear that for any two menus A0 ; B 0 with A0 2 B 0 we must necessarily have (C A0 ) [ [D (A0 [ B 0 )] 2 (C B 0 ) [ [D (A0 [ B 0 )] when is large, so that C and D preserve %2 in the limit. [Su¢ ciency] Suppose that %1 and %2 have PAEU representations with priors 1 and 2 , respectively, and suppose that %2 can be extracted from %1 . Fix any Borel set T U such that 2 (T ) = 1 and for any Borel subset T^ of T , 2 (T^) = 0 =) ^ 1 (T ) = 0. By Lemma 9 above, we know that such a set always exists. We need the following claim: Claim 2. Let S1 := supp ( 1 ). It must be the case that Proof of Claim. Suppose of (X) and de…ne A := E and B :=

2

2

(T \ S1 ) = 1:

(T n S1 ) > 0. Let E be any closed sphere in the interior

p 2 E : fpg = arg max Eq (u) for some u 2 S1 : q2E

Notice that, by construction, f A > B g = U nS1 and f A = B g = S1 . This implies that Z Z ( A ( A B ) (u) 2 (du) = B ) (u) 2 (du) > 0; T nS1

U

or, equivalently, A 2 B. Now pick any two menus C; D. For each 2 (0; 1), de…ne f := (C A)[[D (A[B)] 2 (0; 1) ; (C B)[[D (A[B)] . Now note that, for any Z

f (u)

1

(du) =

U

=

Z

ZS1 S1

= 0: 41

f (u) 0

1

1

(du)

(du)

Since C; D were entirely arbitrary, this contradicts the assumption that %2 can be extracted from %1 and, therefore, we conclude that 2 (T \ S1 ) = 1: k Given the claim above, we now assume, without loss of generality, that T S1 . If 1 (T ) = 0, the proof is complete, so assume that 1 (T ) > 0. If 2 is not the Bayesian update of 1 after the observation of T , by a separation argument, we can …nd a continuous function f : U ! R such that Z

f (u)

2

(du) > 0, but

T

Z

f (u)

1

(du) < 0:

T

Let := max jf (u)j ; u2U

and let " > 0 be such that "
0 such that jr (

A

(u)

B

(u))

h (u)j
Dg

f

=

A

Z

h (u) Z

1

(du)

T

=

+ Z

f

+ Z

f

1

1

" (du) + 3 Z T nf

h (u)

(du) :

+ Z

T

< 0:

43

C > Dg

1

(du) +

" 3

1

(du) +

" 3

(du) h (u)

C > D gnT

f (u)

1

1

((f

f (u)

(du) +

C

1

h (u)

1

1

T


D gnT

h (u)

TZ


Dg

f

>

Dg

(T n T 0 )

n T ) n T 00 ) +

(du) + "

" 3

1

(du)

So, for

large enough we must necessarily have (C

B) [ [D

(A [ B)]

1

(C

A) [ [D

(A [ B)] ;

which contradicts the assumption that %2 can be extracted from %1 . We conclude that 2 must be the Bayesian update of 1 after the observation of T: References Dekel, E., B. L. Lipman, and A. Rustichini (2001). Representing preferences with a unique subjective state space. Econometrica 69 (4), 891–934. Dekel, E., B. L. Lipman, and A. Rustichini (2008). Temptation-driven preferences. Review of Economic Studies (Forthcoming). Dekel, E., B. L. Lipman, A. Rustichini, and T. Sarver (2007). Representing preferences with a unique subjective state space: a corrigendum. Econometrica 75 (2), 591–600. Epstein, L. G. (2006). An axiomatic model of non-bayesian updating. Review of ½ Economic Studies 73, 413U436. Epstein, L. G. and M. Le Breton (1993). Dynamically consistent beliefs must be bayesian. Journal of Economic Theory 61, 1–22. Epstein, L. G., M. Marinacci, and K. Seo (2007). Coarse contingencies and ambi½ guity. Theoretical Economics 2, 355U394. Epstein, L. G., J. Noor, and A. Sandroni (2008). Non-bayesian updating: a theoretical framework. Theoretical Economics 3, 193–229. Epstein, L. G. and M. Schneider (2003). Recursive multiple-priors. Journal of Economic Theory 113, 1–31. Ghirardato, P. (2002). Revisiting savage in a conditional world. Economic Theory 20, 83–92. Gilboa, I. and D. Schmeidler (1989). Maxmim expected utility with non-unique prior. Journal of Mathematical Economics 18 (2), 141–153. Gilboa, I. and D. Schmeidler (1993). Updating ambiguous beliefs. Journal of Economic Theory 59 (1), 33–49. 44

Gul, F. and W. Pesendorfer (2001). rica 69 (6), 1403–1435.

Temptation and self-control.

Economet-

Hanany, E. and P. Klibano¤ (2007). Updating preferences with multiple priors. Theoretical Economics 2, 261–298. Koopmans, T. C. (1964). On ‡exibility of future preferences. In M. W. Shelly and G. L. Bryan (Eds.), Human Judgments and Optimality, pp. 243–254. New York: John Wiley and Sons. Kreps, D. M. (1979). A representation theorem for "preference for ‡exibility". Econometrica 47 (3), 565–578. Nehring, K. (1999). Preference for ‡exibility in a savage framework. Econometrica 67 (1), 101–119. Rockafellar, R. T. (1997). Convex Analysis. Princeton Landmarks in Mathematics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Sarver, T. (2008). Anticipating regret: Why fewer options may be better. Econometrica 76 (2), 263–305. Siniscalchi, M. (2006). Dynamic choice under ambiguity. mimeo.

45

Banco Central do Brasil Trabalhos para Discussão Os Trabalhos para Discussão podem ser acessados na internet, no formato PDF, no endereço: http://www.bc.gov.br

Working Paper Series Working Papers in PDF format can be downloaded from: http://www.bc.gov.br

1

Implementing Inflation Targeting in Brazil Joel Bogdanski, Alexandre Antonio Tombini and Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang

Jul/2000

2

Política Monetária e Supervisão do Sistema Financeiro Nacional no Banco Central do Brasil Eduardo Lundberg

Jul/2000

Monetary Policy and Banking Supervision Functions on the Central Bank Eduardo Lundberg

Jul/2000

3

Private Sector Participation: a Theoretical Justification of the Brazilian Position Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang

Jul/2000

4

An Information Theory Approach to the Aggregation of Log-Linear Models Pedro H. Albuquerque

Jul/2000

5

The Pass-Through from Depreciation to Inflation: a Panel Study Ilan Goldfajn and Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang

Jul/2000

6

Optimal Interest Rate Rules in Inflation Targeting Frameworks José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto, Fabio Araújo and Marta Baltar J. Moreira

Jul/2000

7

Leading Indicators of Inflation for Brazil Marcelle Chauvet

Sep/2000

8

The Correlation Matrix of the Brazilian Central Bank’s Standard Model for Interest Rate Market Risk José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto

Sep/2000

9

Estimating Exchange Market Pressure and Intervention Activity Emanuel-Werner Kohlscheen

Nov/2000

10

Análise do Financiamento Externo a uma Pequena Economia Aplicação da Teoria do Prêmio Monetário ao Caso Brasileiro: 1991–1998 Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Renato Galvão Flôres Júnior

Mar/2001

11

A Note on the Efficient Estimation of Inflation in Brazil Michael F. Bryan and Stephen G. Cecchetti

Mar/2001

12

A Test of Competition in Brazilian Banking Márcio I. Nakane

Mar/2001

46

13

Modelos de Previsão de Insolvência Bancária no Brasil Marcio Magalhães Janot

Mar/2001

14

Evaluating Core Inflation Measures for Brazil Francisco Marcos Rodrigues Figueiredo

Mar/2001

15

Is It Worth Tracking Dollar/Real Implied Volatility? Sandro Canesso de Andrade and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Mar/2001

16

Avaliação das Projeções do Modelo Estrutural do Banco Central do Brasil para a Taxa de Variação do IPCA Sergio Afonso Lago Alves

Mar/2001

Evaluation of the Central Bank of Brazil Structural Model’s Inflation Forecasts in an Inflation Targeting Framework Sergio Afonso Lago Alves

Jul/2001

Estimando o Produto Potencial Brasileiro: uma Abordagem de Função de Produção Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

Abr/2001

Estimating Brazilian Potential Output: a Production Function Approach Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

Aug/2002

18

A Simple Model for Inflation Targeting in Brazil Paulo Springer de Freitas and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Apr/2001

19

Uncovered Interest Parity with Fundamentals: a Brazilian Exchange Rate Forecast Model Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos, Paulo Springer de Freitas and Fabio Araújo

May/2001

20

Credit Channel without the LM Curve Victorio Y. T. Chu and Márcio I. Nakane

May/2001

21

Os Impactos Econômicos da CPMF: Teoria e Evidência Pedro H. Albuquerque

Jun/2001

22

Decentralized Portfolio Management Paulo Coutinho and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Jun/2001

23

Os Efeitos da CPMF sobre a Intermediação Financeira Sérgio Mikio Koyama e Márcio I. Nakane

Jul/2001

24

Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Shocks, Backward-Looking Prices, and IMF Conditionality Joel Bogdanski, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and Alexandre Antonio Tombini

Aug/2001

25

Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Reviewing Two Years of Monetary Policy 1999/00 Pedro Fachada

Aug/2001

26

Inflation Targeting in an Open Financially Integrated Emerging Economy: the Case of Brazil Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Aug/2001

27

Complementaridade e Fungibilidade dos Fluxos de Capitais Internacionais Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Renato Galvão Flôres Júnior

Set/2001

17

47

28

Regras Monetárias e Dinâmica Macroeconômica no Brasil: uma Abordagem de Expectativas Racionais Marco Antonio Bonomo e Ricardo D. Brito

Nov/2001

29

Using a Money Demand Model to Evaluate Monetary Policies in Brazil Pedro H. Albuquerque and Solange Gouvêa

Nov/2001

30

Testing the Expectations Hypothesis in the Brazilian Term Structure of Interest Rates Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Sandro Canesso de Andrade

Nov/2001

31

Algumas Considerações sobre a Sazonalidade no IPCA Francisco Marcos R. Figueiredo e Roberta Blass Staub

Nov/2001

32

Crises Cambiais e Ataques Especulativos no Brasil Mauro Costa Miranda

Nov/2001

33

Monetary Policy and Inflation in Brazil (1975-2000): a VAR Estimation André Minella

Nov/2001

34

Constrained Discretion and Collective Action Problems: Reflections on the Resolution of International Financial Crises Arminio Fraga and Daniel Luiz Gleizer

Nov/2001

35

Uma Definição Operacional de Estabilidade de Preços Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

Dez/2001

36

Can Emerging Markets Float? Should They Inflation Target? Barry Eichengreen

Feb/2002

37

Monetary Policy in Brazil: Remarks on the Inflation Targeting Regime, Public Debt Management and Open Market Operations Luiz Fernando Figueiredo, Pedro Fachada and Sérgio Goldenstein

Mar/2002

38

Volatilidade Implícita e Antecipação de Eventos de Stress: um Teste para o Mercado Brasileiro Frederico Pechir Gomes

Mar/2002

39

Opções sobre Dólar Comercial e Expectativas a Respeito do Comportamento da Taxa de Câmbio Paulo Castor de Castro

Mar/2002

40

Speculative Attacks on Debts, Dollarization and Optimum Currency Areas Aloisio Araujo and Márcia Leon

Apr/2002

41

Mudanças de Regime no Câmbio Brasileiro Carlos Hamilton V. Araújo e Getúlio B. da Silveira Filho

Jun/2002

42

Modelo Estrutural com Setor Externo: Endogenização do Prêmio de Risco e do Câmbio Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos, Sérgio Afonso Lago Alves e Gil Riella

Jun/2002

43

The Effects of the Brazilian ADRs Program on Domestic Market Efficiency Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Eduardo José Araújo Lima

Jun/2002

48

Jun/2002

44

Estrutura Competitiva, Produtividade Industrial e Liberação Comercial no Brasil Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira e Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho Guillén

45

Optimal Monetary Policy, Gains from Commitment, and Inflation Persistence André Minella

Aug/2002

46

The Determinants of Bank Interest Spread in Brazil Tarsila Segalla Afanasieff, Priscilla Maria Villa Lhacer and Márcio I. Nakane

Aug/2002

47

Indicadores Derivados de Agregados Monetários Fernando de Aquino Fonseca Neto e José Albuquerque Júnior

Set/2002

48

Should Government Smooth Exchange Rate Risk? Ilan Goldfajn and Marcos Antonio Silveira

Sep/2002

49

Desenvolvimento do Sistema Financeiro e Crescimento Econômico no Brasil: Evidências de Causalidade Orlando Carneiro de Matos

Set/2002

50

Macroeconomic Coordination and Inflation Targeting in a Two-Country Model Eui Jung Chang, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Joanílio Rodolpho Teixeira

Sep/2002

51

Credit Channel with Sovereign Credit Risk: an Empirical Test Victorio Yi Tson Chu

Sep/2002

52

Generalized Hyperbolic Distributions and Brazilian Data José Fajardo and Aquiles Farias

Sep/2002

53

Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Lessons and Challenges André Minella, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Nov/2002

54

Stock Returns and Volatility Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Solange Maria Guerra

Nov/2002

55

Componentes de Curto e Longo Prazo das Taxas de Juros no Brasil Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho de Guillén

Nov/2002

56

Causality and Cointegration in Stock Markets: the Case of Latin America Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Eduardo José Araújo Lima

Dec/2002

57

As Leis de Falência: uma Abordagem Econômica Aloisio Araujo

Dez/2002

58

The Random Walk Hypothesis and the Behavior of Foreign Capital Portfolio Flows: the Brazilian Stock Market Case Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Dec/2002

59

Os Preços Administrados e a Inflação no Brasil Francisco Marcos R. Figueiredo e Thaís Porto Ferreira

Dez/2002

60

Delegated Portfolio Management Paulo Coutinho and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Dec/2002

49

61

O Uso de Dados de Alta Freqüência na Estimação da Volatilidade e do Valor em Risco para o Ibovespa João Maurício de Souza Moreira e Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Dez/2002

62

Taxa de Juros e Concentração Bancária no Brasil Eduardo Kiyoshi Tonooka e Sérgio Mikio Koyama

Fev/2003

63

Optimal Monetary Rules: the Case of Brazil Charles Lima de Almeida, Marco Aurélio Peres, Geraldo da Silva e Souza and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Feb/2003

64

Medium-Size Macroeconomic Model for the Brazilian Economy Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Sergio Afonso Lago Alves

Feb/2003

65

On the Information Content of Oil Future Prices Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Feb/2003

66

A Taxa de Juros de Equilíbrio: uma Abordagem Múltipla Pedro Calhman de Miranda e Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Fev/2003

67

Avaliação de Métodos de Cálculo de Exigência de Capital para Risco de Mercado de Carteiras de Ações no Brasil Gustavo S. Araújo, João Maurício S. Moreira e Ricardo S. Maia Clemente

Fev/2003

68

Real Balances in the Utility Function: Evidence for Brazil Leonardo Soriano de Alencar and Márcio I. Nakane

Feb/2003

69

r-filters: a Hodrick-Prescott Filter Generalization Fabio Araújo, Marta Baltar Moreira Areosa and José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto

Feb/2003

70

Monetary Policy Surprises and the Brazilian Term Structure of Interest Rates Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Feb/2003

71

On Shadow-Prices of Banks in Real-Time Gross Settlement Systems Rodrigo Penaloza

Apr/2003

72

O Prêmio pela Maturidade na Estrutura a Termo das Taxas de Juros Brasileiras Ricardo Dias de Oliveira Brito, Angelo J. Mont'Alverne Duarte e Osmani Teixeira de C. Guillen

Maio/2003

73

Análise de Componentes Principais de Dados Funcionais – uma Aplicação às Estruturas a Termo de Taxas de Juros Getúlio Borges da Silveira e Octavio Bessada

Maio/2003

74

Aplicação do Modelo de Black, Derman & Toy à Precificação de Opções Sobre Títulos de Renda Fixa Octavio Manuel Bessada Lion, Carlos Alberto Nunes Cosenza e César das Neves

Maio/2003

75

Brazil’s Financial System: Resilience to Shocks, no Currency Substitution, but Struggling to Promote Growth Ilan Goldfajn, Katherine Hennings and Helio Mori

50

Jun/2003

76

Inflation Targeting in Emerging Market Economies Arminio Fraga, Ilan Goldfajn and André Minella

Jun/2003

77

Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Constructing Credibility under Exchange Rate Volatility André Minella, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Jul/2003

78

Contornando os Pressupostos de Black & Scholes: Aplicação do Modelo de Precificação de Opções de Duan no Mercado Brasileiro Gustavo Silva Araújo, Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Antonio Carlos Figueiredo, Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Out/2003

79

Inclusão do Decaimento Temporal na Metodologia Delta-Gama para o Cálculo do VaR de Carteiras Compradas em Opções no Brasil Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Gustavo Silva Araújo, Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Out/2003

80

Diferenças e Semelhanças entre Países da América Latina: uma Análise de Markov Switching para os Ciclos Econômicos de Brasil e Argentina Arnildo da Silva Correa

Out/2003

81

Bank Competition, Agency Costs and the Performance of the Monetary Policy Leonardo Soriano de Alencar and Márcio I. Nakane

Jan/2004

82

Carteiras de Opções: Avaliação de Metodologias de Exigência de Capital no Mercado Brasileiro Cláudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo e Gustavo Silva Araújo

Mar/2004

83

Does Inflation Targeting Reduce Inflation? An Analysis for the OECD Industrial Countries Thomas Y. Wu

May/2004

84

Speculative Attacks on Debts and Optimum Currency Area: a Welfare Analysis Aloisio Araujo and Marcia Leon

May/2004

85

Risk Premia for Emerging Markets Bonds: Evidence from Brazilian Government Debt, 1996-2002 André Soares Loureiro and Fernando de Holanda Barbosa

May/2004

86

Identificação do Fator Estocástico de Descontos e Algumas Implicações sobre Testes de Modelos de Consumo Fabio Araujo e João Victor Issler

Maio/2004

87

Mercado de Crédito: uma Análise Econométrica dos Volumes de Crédito Total e Habitacional no Brasil Ana Carla Abrão Costa

Dez/2004

88

Ciclos Internacionais de Negócios: uma Análise de Mudança de Regime Markoviano para Brasil, Argentina e Estados Unidos Arnildo da Silva Correa e Ronald Otto Hillbrecht

Dez/2004

89

O Mercado de Hedge Cambial no Brasil: Reação das Instituições Financeiras a Intervenções do Banco Central Fernando N. de Oliveira

Dez/2004

51

90

Bank Privatization and Productivity: Evidence for Brazil Márcio I. Nakane and Daniela B. Weintraub

Dec/2004

91

Credit Risk Measurement and the Regulation of Bank Capital and Provision Requirements in Brazil – a Corporate Analysis Ricardo Schechtman, Valéria Salomão Garcia, Sergio Mikio Koyama and Guilherme Cronemberger Parente

Dec/2004

92

Steady-State Analysis of an Open Economy General Equilibrium Model for Brazil Mirta Noemi Sataka Bugarin, Roberto de Goes Ellery Jr., Victor Gomes Silva, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Apr/2005

93

Avaliação de Modelos de Cálculo de Exigência de Capital para Risco Cambial Claudio H. da S. Barbedo, Gustavo S. Araújo, João Maurício S. Moreira e Ricardo S. Maia Clemente

Abr/2005

94

Simulação Histórica Filtrada: Incorporação da Volatilidade ao Modelo Histórico de Cálculo de Risco para Ativos Não-Lineares Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Gustavo Silva Araújo e Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Abr/2005

95

Comment on Market Discipline and Monetary Policy by Carl Walsh Maurício S. Bugarin and Fábia A. de Carvalho

Apr/2005

96

O que É Estratégia: uma Abordagem Multiparadigmática para a Disciplina Anthero de Moraes Meirelles

Ago/2005

97

Finance and the Business Cycle: a Kalman Filter Approach with Markov Switching Ryan A. Compton and Jose Ricardo da Costa e Silva

Aug/2005

98

Capital Flows Cycle: Stylized Facts and Empirical Evidences for Emerging Market Economies Helio Mori e Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Aug/2005

99

Adequação das Medidas de Valor em Risco na Formulação da Exigência de Capital para Estratégias de Opções no Mercado Brasileiro Gustavo Silva Araújo, Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo,e Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Set/2005

100 Targets and Inflation Dynamics Sergio A. L. Alves and Waldyr D. Areosa

Oct/2005

101 Comparing Equilibrium Real Interest Rates: Different Approaches to Measure Brazilian Rates Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Márcio I. Nakane

Mar/2006

102 Judicial Risk and Credit Market Performance: Micro Evidence from Brazilian Payroll Loans Ana Carla A. Costa and João M. P. de Mello

Apr/2006

103 The Effect of Adverse Supply Shocks on Monetary Policy and Output Maria da Glória D. S. Araújo, Mirta Bugarin, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Jose Ricardo C. Silva

Apr/2006

52

104 Extração de Informação de Opções Cambiais no Brasil Eui Jung Chang e Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Abr/2006

105 Representing Roommate’s Preferences with Symmetric Utilities José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto

Apr/2006

106 Testing Nonlinearities Between Brazilian Exchange Rates and Inflation Volatilities Cristiane R. Albuquerque and Marcelo Portugal

May/2006

107 Demand for Bank Services and Market Power in Brazilian Banking Márcio I. Nakane, Leonardo S. Alencar and Fabio Kanczuk

Jun/2006

108 O Efeito da Consignação em Folha nas Taxas de Juros dos Empréstimos Pessoais Eduardo A. S. Rodrigues, Victorio Chu, Leonardo S. Alencar e Tony Takeda

Jun/2006

109 The Recent Brazilian Disinflation Process and Costs Alexandre A. Tombini and Sergio A. Lago Alves

Jun/2006

110 Fatores de Risco e o Spread Bancário no Brasil Fernando G. Bignotto e Eduardo Augusto de Souza Rodrigues

Jul/2006

111 Avaliação de Modelos de Exigência de Capital para Risco de Mercado do Cupom Cambial Alan Cosme Rodrigues da Silva, João Maurício de Souza Moreira e Myrian Beatriz Eiras das Neves

Jul/2006

112 Interdependence and Contagion: an Analysis of Information Transmission in Latin America's Stock Markets Angelo Marsiglia Fasolo

Jul/2006

113 Investigação da Memória de Longo Prazo da Taxa de Câmbio no Brasil Sergio Rubens Stancato de Souza, Benjamin Miranda Tabak e Daniel O. Cajueiro

Ago/2006

114 The Inequality Channel of Monetary Transmission Marta Areosa and Waldyr Areosa

Aug/2006

115 Myopic Loss Aversion and House-Money Effect Overseas: an Experimental Approach José L. B. Fernandes, Juan Ignacio Peña and Benjamin M. Tabak

Sep/2006

116 Out-Of-The-Money Monte Carlo Simulation Option Pricing: the Join Use of Importance Sampling and Descriptive Sampling Jaqueline Terra Moura Marins, Eduardo Saliby and Joséte Florencio dos Santos

Sep/2006

117 An Analysis of Off-Site Supervision of Banks’ Profitability, Risk and Capital Adequacy: a Portfolio Simulation Approach Applied to Brazilian Banks Theodore M. Barnhill, Marcos R. Souto and Benjamin M. Tabak

Sep/2006

118 Contagion, Bankruptcy and Social Welfare Analysis in a Financial Economy with Risk Regulation Constraint Aloísio P. Araújo and José Valentim M. Vicente

Oct/2006

53

119 A Central de Risco de Crédito no Brasil: uma Análise de Utilidade de Informação Ricardo Schechtman

Out/2006

120 Forecasting Interest Rates: an Application for Brazil Eduardo J. A. Lima, Felipe Luduvice and Benjamin M. Tabak

Oct/2006

121 The Role of Consumer’s Risk Aversion on Price Rigidity Sergio A. Lago Alves and Mirta N. S. Bugarin

Nov/2006

122 Nonlinear Mechanisms of the Exchange Rate Pass-Through: a Phillips Curve Model With Threshold for Brazil Arnildo da Silva Correa and André Minella

Nov/2006

123 A Neoclassical Analysis of the Brazilian “Lost-Decades” Flávia Mourão Graminho

Nov/2006

124 The Dynamic Relations between Stock Prices and Exchange Rates: Evidence for Brazil Benjamin M. Tabak

Nov/2006

125 Herding Behavior by Equity Foreign Investors on Emerging Markets Barbara Alemanni and José Renato Haas Ornelas

Dec/2006

126 Risk Premium: Insights over the Threshold José L. B. Fernandes, Augusto Hasman and Juan Ignacio Peña

Dec/2006

127 Uma Investigação Baseada em Reamostragem sobre Requerimentos de Capital para Risco de Crédito no Brasil Ricardo Schechtman

Dec/2006

128 Term Structure Movements Implicit in Option Prices Caio Ibsen R. Almeida and José Valentim M. Vicente

Dec/2006

129 Brazil: Taming Inflation Expectations Afonso S. Bevilaqua, Mário Mesquita and André Minella

Jan/2007

130 The Role of Banks in the Brazilian Interbank Market: Does Bank Type Matter? Daniel O. Cajueiro and Benjamin M. Tabak

Jan/2007

131 Long-Range Dependence in Exchange Rates: the Case of the European Monetary System Sergio Rubens Stancato de Souza, Benjamin M. Tabak and Daniel O. Cajueiro

Mar/2007

132 Credit Risk Monte Carlo Simulation Using Simplified Creditmetrics’ Model: the Joint Use of Importance Sampling and Descriptive Sampling Jaqueline Terra Moura Marins and Eduardo Saliby

Mar/2007

133 A New Proposal for Collection and Generation of Information on Financial Institutions’ Risk: the Case of Derivatives Gilneu F. A. Vivan and Benjamin M. Tabak

Mar/2007

134 Amostragem Descritiva no Apreçamento de Opções Européias através de Simulação Monte Carlo: o Efeito da Dimensionalidade e da Probabilidade de Exercício no Ganho de Precisão Eduardo Saliby, Sergio Luiz Medeiros Proença de Gouvêa e Jaqueline Terra Moura Marins

Abr/2007

54

135 Evaluation of Default Risk for the Brazilian Banking Sector Marcelo Y. Takami and Benjamin M. Tabak

May/2007

136 Identifying Volatility Risk Premium from Fixed Income Asian Options Caio Ibsen R. Almeida and José Valentim M. Vicente

May/2007

137 Monetary Policy Design under Competing Models of Inflation Persistence Solange Gouvea e Abhijit Sen Gupta

May/2007

138 Forecasting Exchange Rate Density Using Parametric Models: the Case of Brazil Marcos M. Abe, Eui J. Chang and Benjamin M. Tabak

May/2007

139 Selection of Optimal Lag Length inCointegrated VAR Models with Weak Form of Common Cyclical Features Carlos Enrique Carrasco Gutiérrez, Reinaldo Castro Souza and Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho Guillén

Jun/2007

140 Inflation Targeting, Credibility and Confidence Crises Rafael Santos and Aloísio Araújo

Aug/2007

141 Forecasting Bonds Yields in the Brazilian Fixed income Market Jose Vicente and Benjamin M. Tabak

Aug/2007

142 Crises Análise da Coerência de Medidas de Risco no Mercado Brasileiro de Ações e Desenvolvimento de uma Metodologia Híbrida para o Expected Shortfall Alan Cosme Rodrigues da Silva, Eduardo Facó Lemgruber, José Alberto Rebello Baranowski e Renato da Silva Carvalho

Ago/2007

143 Price Rigidity in Brazil: Evidence from CPI Micro Data Solange Gouvea

Sep/2007

144 The Effect of Bid-Ask Prices on Brazilian Options Implied Volatility: a Case Study of Telemar Call Options Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo and Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Oct/2007

145 The Stability-Concentration Relationship in the Brazilian Banking System Benjamin Miranda Tabak, Solange Maria Guerra, Eduardo José Araújo Lima and Eui Jung Chang

Oct/2007

146 Movimentos da Estrutura a Termo e Critérios de Minimização do Erro de Previsão em um Modelo Paramétrico Exponencial Caio Almeida, Romeu Gomes, André Leite e José Vicente

Out/2007

147 Explaining Bank Failures in Brazil: Micro, Macro and Contagion Effects (1994-1998) Adriana Soares Sales and Maria Eduarda Tannuri-Pianto

Oct/2007

148 Um Modelo de Fatores Latentes com Variáveis Macroeconômicas para a Curva de Cupom Cambial Felipe Pinheiro, Caio Almeida e José Vicente

Out/2007

149 Joint Validation of Credit Rating PDs under Default Correlation Ricardo Schechtman

Oct/2007

55

150 A Probabilistic Approach for Assessing the Significance of Contextual Variables in Nonparametric Frontier Models: an Application for Brazilian Banks Roberta Blass Staub and Geraldo da Silva e Souza

Oct/2007

151 Building Confidence Intervals with Block Bootstraps for the Variance Ratio Test of Predictability Eduardo José Araújo Lima and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Nov/2007

152 Demand for Foreign Exchange Derivatives in Brazil: Hedge or Speculation? Fernando N. de Oliveira and Walter Novaes

Dec/2007

153 Aplicação da Amostragem por Importância à Simulação de Opções Asiáticas Fora do Dinheiro Jaqueline Terra Moura Marins

Dez/2007

154 Identification of Monetary Policy Shocks in the Brazilian Market for Bank Reserves Adriana Soares Sales and Maria Tannuri-Pianto

Dec/2007

155 Does Curvature Enhance Forecasting? Caio Almeida, Romeu Gomes, André Leite and José Vicente

Dec/2007

156 Escolha do Banco e Demanda por Empréstimos: um Modelo de Decisão em Duas Etapas Aplicado para o Brasil Sérgio Mikio Koyama e Márcio I. Nakane

Dez/2007

157 Is the Investment-Uncertainty Link Really Elusive? The Harmful Effects of Inflation Uncertainty in Brazil Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

Jan/2008

158 Characterizing the Brazilian Term Structure of Interest Rates Osmani T. Guillen and Benjamin M. Tabak

Feb/2008

159 Behavior and Effects of Equity Foreign Investors on Emerging Markets Barbara Alemanni and José Renato Haas Ornelas

Feb/2008

160 The Incidence of Reserve Requirements in Brazil: Do Bank Stockholders Share the Burden? Fábia A. de Carvalho and Cyntia F. Azevedo

Feb/2008

161 Evaluating Value-at-Risk Models via Quantile Regressions Wagner P. Gaglianone, Luiz Renato Lima and Oliver Linton

Feb/2008

162 Balance Sheet Effects in Currency Crises: Evidence from Brazil Marcio M. Janot, Márcio G. P. Garcia and Walter Novaes

Apr/2008

163 Searching for the Natural Rate of Unemployment in a Large Relative Price Shocks’ Economy: the Brazilian Case Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

May/2008

164 Foreign Banks’ Entry and Departure: the recent Brazilian experience (1996-2006) Pedro Fachada

Jun/2008

165 Avaliação de Opções de Troca e Opções de Spread Européias e Americanas Giuliano Carrozza Uzêda Iorio de Souza, Carlos Patrício Samanez e Gustavo Santos Raposo

Jul/2008

56

166 Testing Hyperinflation Theories Using the Inflation Tax Curve: a case study Fernando de Holanda Barbosa and Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

Jul/2008

167 O Poder Discriminante das Operações de Crédito das Instituições Financeiras Brasileiras Clodoaldo Aparecido Annibal

Jul/2008

168 An Integrated Model for Liquidity Management and Short-Term Asset Allocation in Commercial Banks Wenersamy Ramos de Alcântara

Jul/2008

169 Mensuração do Risco Sistêmico no Setor Bancário com Variáveis Contábeis e Econômicas Lucio Rodrigues Capelletto, Eliseu Martins e Luiz João Corrar

Jul/2008

170 Política de Fechamento de Bancos com Regulador Não-Benevolente: Resumo e Aplicação Adriana Soares Sales

Jul/2008

171 Modelos para a Utilização das Operações de Redesconto pelos Bancos com Carteira Comercial no Brasil Sérgio Mikio Koyama e Márcio Issao Nakane

Ago/2008

172 Combining Hodrick-Prescott Filtering with a Production Function Approach to Estimate Output Gap Marta Areosa

Aug/2008

173 Exchange Rate Dynamics and the Relationship between the Random Walk Hypothesis and Official Interventions Eduardo José Araújo Lima and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Aug/2008

174 Foreign Exchange Market Volatility Information: an investigation of real-dollar exchange rate Frederico Pechir Gomes, Marcelo Yoshio Takami and Vinicius Ratton Brandi

Aug/2008

175 Evaluating Asset Pricing Models in a Fama-French Framework Carlos Enrique Carrasco Gutierrez and Wagner Piazza Gaglianone

Dec/2008

176 Fiat Money and the Value of Binding Portfolio Constraints Mário R. Páscoa, Myrian Petrassi and Juan Pablo Torres-Martínez

Dec/2008

57