Profitable Destabilizing Speculation as Intertemporal ... - SAGE Journals

2 downloads 0 Views 534KB Size Report
PROFITABLE DESTABILIZING SPECULATION AS INTERTEMPORAL PRICE. DISCRIMINATION by David H. Feldman and Edward Tower*. In "The Case for ...
PROFITABLE DESTABILIZING SPECULATION AS INTERTEMPORAL PRICE DISCRIMINATION byDavid H. Feldman and Edward Tower* In "The Case forFlexible Exchange Rates" Milton Friedman [4, p. 175] developed the proposition that destabilizing speculation is necessarily

unprofitable.

On

the same

page

through,he qualified his proposition by not ing that a full analysis of the problem would require a satisfactory definition of exactly what constituted both speculation and desta bilizing behavior. He recognized that it is difficultto separatewhat he analyzed, namely in the sense of purchasing "pure speculation" now for resale later under conditions of un from other sorts of transactions. certainty, for example, the "speculator" who Consider, to set price. This could his power recognizes come together to be a group of sellers who form a cartel. In this paper we explore how can earn profit by intertem such a speculator porally

destabilizing

worsen

the welfare

the price. Moreover,

note that destabilization may

we

improve or

of nonspeculators.

The literatureon destabilizing speculation

has passed through a number of stages. Early to refute Friedman's attempts proposition rested on very particular counter-examples. Baumol around [1] built a counter-example

unrealized paper profits and Kemp one

based

speculative

on a excess

backward bending demand function.

[2] built non

In the

late 60s Farrell [2] showed that in the pres

ence of a fluctuating excess demand function an increase in the variance of price could if the ex accompany profitable speculation cess demand in each time period function is in as of other prices independent periods, long as it is nonlinear covers and the speculation more than two time periods.1 He did not, on state conditions however, nonspeculative

demand under which profit fromprice desta bilization

actually

would

occur.2

Newberry's analysis [8] of stochastic limit

pricing3 is closer to ours in that the profita bility of a destabilized price is explored in the context

of a speculator-producer

with market

power. Newberry shows that price destabili zation may be both profitable and welfare improving to nonspeculators (relative to a fixed pricemonopoly outcome) iftheprice is randomized

between

values

above

and below

the limitprice and if themonopoly price is sufficientlygreater than marginal cost.4 He argues that the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand must be falling suffi ciently rapidly at the limitprice in order for price destabilization of this sort to be profit able.

This condition, is overly strong. however, a We reve nonmonotonic identify marginal nue curve as the source of the profitability of to a pro price destabilization intertemporal

= ducer-speculator. Since MR P(I I/77), where 77is the absolute value of the price elasticity

of demand,

nonmonotonic

MR

can

arise only when this elasticity falls with in

et al. (3) creased price. However, Formby have shown that the conditions under which revenue is upward marginal sloping are not

as stringentas formerly thought. Positively revenue can be generated by sloping marginal con of well behaved simple transformations vex demand functions.5

I. Inelastic Supply In order to focus on the intuition behind the problem we first consider the simplest necessary

possible

diagram

between

F and D'.6

tomake

the point.

In figure 1 SBS' is themarginal cost of pro is the demand curve, duction and DAEFD' which isflat in rangesDA and EF, has unitary elasticity between A and E and is vertical The

corresponding

mar

* Colgate University, and Duke University, respectively. Our thanks toAnthony Brewer and Kent Kimbrough for helpful insightson earlier drafts and to an anonymous refereewho helped shape this version. Remaining errors are the property of the authors. Parts of this paper were written while Feldman and Tower were visiting at Duke and Simon Fraser Universities, respectively. 60 Sage Publications Inc. is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve, and extend access to The American Economist www.jstor.org

®

from the supply curve of figure 1.OALL'

s

revenue

the total

curve

is

that corresponds

to

figure 1 's demand curve. By destabilizing the the

price

total

revenue

attainable

production level between A'

for any

and R will lie

Thus the marginal along the segment AT'. revenue curve ismade convex. The cartel will

B. 0 S .I

ID

choose to produce at R and destabilize the price as long as the slope of AT' exceeds the slope ofOC, or in otherwords as long as the modified marginal revenue exceeds marginal

|A 'E

Quantity

ij'

! ! IMC2/V\! \ \!B' I 1/ // \c? MC4

ginal

Com

at A, with an obvious the market loss to consumers (an efficiency cost

as well), and monopoly profits to be divided

between

was discrimination price in the preceding analysis be

cause of the upward discontinuous jump in revenue

the marginal

curve.

This

issue

is

the total cost curve, C, to reflect cost. The total revenue curve, rising marginal

petitive equilibrium is at E. Suppose that the suppliers forma cartel but feel constrained to maintain a fixed price. They will choose to supply welfare

II. The General Case

have

1and 2

is DAA'REFD'.

be profitable.9,10

demonstrated more generally infigure 3.We

*Z

curve

may

Intertemporal made profitable 0 \Quantity

revenue

speculation

\/

\jytf Jy

FIGURES

Such intertemporal price discrimina or raises sup tion, speculation, destabilizing demanders' and eco welfare pliers' profits, nomic efficiency above the levels in the mo

nopolistic uniform price case. This then is found a new sense in which destabilizing

! MC3I

\ MC,,' |

cost.

the suppliers.

Now suppose that the cartel no longerfeels

to supply at a given price all of constrained the time. Suppose also that the cartel has a on intertemporal monopoly storage or, alter

natively, that the good is perishable once

consumers reve the marginal buy it.7 Using nue curve DAA'REFD' the cartel could pro

duce OR units in every period, selling at A a fractionRD'/A'D' of the time and dumping the surplus at the price Pc (above marginal cost) the remaining fractionA'R/A'D' of the time.8The condition under which this inter temporal price discriminationmaximizes car tel profits is shown in figure 2. The kinked curve OC'C is the total cost curve derived

drawn

R, is drawn with inflectionpoints (Ii and I2) so that it isconsistentwith a marginal revenue curve that isboth nonmonotonic and upward sloping

over

part

of the

relevant

range

of

quantities. IfR intersectseach ray from the origin only once, and each time from above, curve has the normal downward the demand slope. The

standard

outcome

monopoly

is pro

duction at D where the vertical distance be teen R and C

In the case of the

ismaximized.

price discriminating cartel the total revenue attainable for any production level between B and E can be made to lie along the segment B'E' by sellingat B' and at E' forappropriate fractions of the market period. The total rev enue curve is again made convex by destabil

izing pricing behavior. To maximize profits the cartel will choose to produce where the vertical distance between themodified total revenue

curve

OB'E'Z

and

the

total

cost

curve ismaximized. This is shown as point A infigure 3. To exhaust itsproduct the cartel must sell at B' a fractionAE/BE of the time 61

Price

Z'B'

A

.

Pc

the marginal

Using

output increases under the cartel's If, however,

_

____.IGV^

or E'Z.

cost curve

derived fromfigure 3's total cost curve (MC2)

S'

price discrimination. single price

optimum

lies to the rightof point S in figures 3 and 4 then price discrimination increases cartel profitsbut reduces the level of output.11

E-F

III. A FurtherGeneralization

S-j-'B

Johnson [6] has analyzed speculation in a general equilibrium framework using an

J-J-J-^Quantity

can also box diagram. We Edgeworth-Bowley do a general equilibrium which sim analysis

C

ply requires us to reinterpretfigure 3. Just

L'

-*" y^ ^ -*"^ S

think of dollars

i I

^X

on the vertical

axis as a second

commodity. Then if the home country im ports dollars and exports Q, R becomes the

if the "do foreign offer curve.12 Furthermore, actor consumes mestic" dollars then C only a domestic becomes trade indifference curve, since all points along it involve zero produc cost curve, when er's surplus, the supplier's

i

shiftedvertically, lays out the entire indiffer

ence map. ()/?-fe-DTQu0ntlty

FIGURES 3 and 4

the cartel

equates

revenue

marginal

periods (the slope ofR at B' and E'). interemporal

arbitrage

of marginal

in both

It is this revenue

that permits profit from destabilizing the price. As with other forms of price discrimi it is not hard to show that consumers' surplus, and economic efficiency, may rise or

nation

fallwith the advent of price discrimination. It is interestingto note that this formof price discrimination does not rest on exploiting preference differences between individuals but rather involves treating identical con sumers

differently

over

time.

and

clearly

shows

the range of situa

tions for which price discrimination is the

outcome. The marginal profit maximizing revenue curve Z'BTiI2Z to the corresponds

total revenue curve in figure 3. The modified

marginal

revenue

curve

is Z'B'A'E'Z.

Price

discrimination will not occur ifmarginal cost intersects

62

marginal

revenue

supplier the domestic

in

the

ranges

in true general

equilib

cum speculator would per private sector to trade con

tinually at the price-quantity point given by the tangency of his trade indifferencecurve to the modified

total revenue

curve. Thus,

in

general equilibrium we see that the optimal solution

for the domestic

country

is to com

bine the use of fluctuating inventorieswith

either state trading or else a fluctuating mum import tariff.

opti

NOTES 1. Farrell's suming

to as independence assumption requires do not store the good that non-speculators

in question. Given

fluctuating

Figure 4 illustratesthe issue usingmarginal

curves

course,

and our mit

and at E' a fractionBA/BE of the time.Thus

Of

rium such vertical parallelism need not hold,

the independence assumption,

non-speculative

excess

demand,

and

no

transactions costs he shows that linearity of the nonspeculative demand function is both necessary and sufficientforFriedman's proposition to hold. 2. Hart [5] dispenses with Farrell's independence as sumption. He finds conditions under which spec ulation is profitable, given that speculation is dis turbing a stationary state equilibrium. Intertem poral price relationships are important toHart but in his model non-speculators make decisions fol lowing ad hoc rules and expectations formation is

notmodelled. It isnot possible to draw conclusions about welfare inHart's frameworkbecause demand price reflectsmarginal utility conditioned on ex pectations which may not be fulfilled. 3. The limit price is the price at which?if itwere expected to persist?oil consumers would be will ing to undertake costly projects to switch to other forms

of energy.

4. His result is not dependent upon assumed behavior toward risk. 5. Consider the demand function q = 600/?"M + 4 500/?~3 which isa summation of constant elasticity functions. This example is presented in Formby, Layson and Smith [3]. 6. Production of mineral water, crude oil or electric power may exhibit this sort of marginal cost step function.

7. Perhaps the good is gasoline and there are econ omies of scale in building storage facilities. Since over marginal sells at a markup cost, the to a non-cartel of storage storer is higher than to a cartel storer.

the cartel cost

8. To maximize profit the cartelwill choose to sell at a rateOA' per period (at price OD) for the largest fraction (#0 of the period possible, subject to the constraint that itbe able to sell the restof itsoutput in the remaining fraction of the period {2). Hence to sell at price OD for as long as possible within each market period requires disposing of the re mainder of itsper period output (at price Pc) at the quickest rate possible consistent with themarket demand

curve,

or at OD'

per period.

Given

4>\OA'

= 1we obtain = + 02 OD' = OR and 0, + 2 fa and fa = A'R/A'D'. RD'/A'D' 9. A logical extension of this argument would involve modeling cartel behavior under conditions of un certainty.This would require some notion of how individual suppliers within the cartel form expec tations about demand conditions. This would more closely identifythe above argument with some of the literatureon destabilizing speculation that has developed

mol

since

Friedman's

[1] and Hart

early work.

See

Bau

[5] and the references cited

therein.

10. Figure 1 can be used to tell a wholly differentstory of destabilizing speculation yet one which yields the same

conclusion

with

respect

to intertemporal

price discrimination. Suppose that supply is com petitive. Furthermore, suppose that suppliers have

become accustomed to selling each period at Pc. Suppose also that a single speculator initiates a forwardmarket and that all sign forward contracts to sell theirwhole output to this speculator at Pc. Assume that the good isperishable so that the total quantity produced in each market period must be sold in that period. Once the speculator has cor nered themarket he will be able to secure a profit of DAGPc in those fractions of themarket period when he sells high while disposing of his excess inventories at cost the restof the time. 11. IfMC intersectsMR such thatwe have two equal profit levels of output then output could rise or fall with the advent of a destabilized price.With price destabilization themodified MR curve has no up ward sloping position. As long asMC is an increas ing function of quantity therewill be a single profit maximizing output choice. 12. For an analysis of what circumstances might give rise to inflectionpoints in the offercurve see Tower (1975). References 1. Baumol, W. J. (1957). Speculation, Profitability, and Stability. Review ofEconomics and Statistics 39 (Aug.): 263-71. 2. Farrell,M. J. (1966) Profitable Speculation. Econ omica 33 (May): 183-93. 3. Formby, J. P., Layson, S. and Smith,W. J. (1982). The Law of Demand, Positive Sloping Marginal Revenue and Multiple Profit Equilibria. Economic Inquiry 20 (April): 303-11. 4. Friedman, M. (1953). Essays inPositive Econom ics,Chicago, 111.: University of Chicago Press. 5. Hart, O. D. (1977). The Profitability of Specula tion. Quarterly Journal of Economics 41 (Nov.): 579-97.

6. Johnson, H. G. (1976) Destabilizing Speculation: A General Equilibrium Approach. Journal ofPolit ical Economy 84 (Feb.): 101-108. 7. Kemp, M. (1963). Speculation, Profitability, and Price Stability.Review ofEconomics and Statistics 45 (May): 185-9. 8. Newberry, D. M. G. (1978). Stochastic Limit Pric ing.Bell Journal ofEconomics 9 (Spring): 260-69. 9. Tower, E. (1975). On theFunctional Relationship Betweeen Tariffs and Welfare. Journal of Interna tionalEconomics 5 (May): 189-199.

63