The Impact of Imports on Price Competition in the Automobile Industry Author(s): Lall B. Ramrattan Source: The American Economist, Vol. 35, No. 2 (Fall, 1991), pp. 60-66 Published by: American Economist Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/25603892 . Accessed: 02/10/2014 14:16 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact
[email protected].
.
American Economist and Omicron Delta Epsilon are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economist.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 169.229.32.36 on Thu, 2 Oct 2014 14:16:53 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE IMPACT OF IMPORTS ON PRICE COMPETITION IN THE AUTOMOBILE INDUSTRY by Lall B. Ramrattan* Price Competition in the Automobile Industry S. automobile firms fol U. Traditionally, lowed a stable policy in pricing cars. General Motors sets its prices based on a target return on its investments, and other firms imitate its price. Brown (1924), General According toDonaldson Motors estimated sales, cost of unit sold, and added a 15 to 20 percent rate of return to its price. the 1960's, the price differences During and General between Ford Motor Company Motors were only $10 to $20; between Chrysler and Ford Motor Company, only Corporation determine
$40 to $50 (Scherer, 1980, p. 181). In the subcompact
category, General Motors'
Chevette
and Ford's Pinto prices differedby only $11 to $73.
For
the
1957-1971
period,
Boyle
Hogarty (1975) found that the U.S. colluded
in their price
behavior
and
firms
in a hedonic
way.
In the 1970's and 1980's, U. S. auto firms newer in several pricing policies adopted response to high oil prices, inflation, interest to rates, and frequent recessions. According R. L. Polk's data (1988, p. 32), the share of imports climbed from 14.53 percent in 1972, to 32.09 percent in 1987. The increase was steady 1982-1987. and between 1978-1982, smaller firms retaliated by making cars, cutting wages, closing plants, improving to reduce efficiency, and adopting measures and discount Dealer's government regulations. customer's rebate were widespread. Chevrolet,
between Domestic
and American Motors Ford Motor Company a "Two-tier" practiced pricing policy, charging in the western lower prices for subcompacts states where import competition was strongest.
started "interim pricing"?a Motors at the increases than usual price followed the of model year by more beginning also tried Firms later. increases basing frequent
General smaller
* Economist Economics
price increases on "product improvement" only. Chrysler Corporation did not follow the leader's policies frequently. In one instance, it priced in direct retaliation to prices of subcompacts imports. The purpose of this paper is to assess whether the increased foreign competition in the 70's and 80's has affected the price behavior of U. S. automobile firms. We used a hedonic price
model developed by Boyle and Hogarty (1975)
to explain price-collusive behavior among do mestic firms for the period 1972-1987. For was the in which traditional years price policy we not maintained, isolated the cheater, and offered explanations for why the hypothesis may have failed. Finally, as it was argued that the U. S. and Japan may have formed an auto cartel via voluntary import quotas, we hypothesized
that domestic and foreign firms may have colluded in price policies for those years in which the hypothesis has failed.
The Model The statistical model for the determination price uniformity is expressed formally thus: Pi,t
=
f(t) [Xut,.Xi,kt,
of
Ui,J,
where p = price, X = quality characteristics, U = time = ith = an error term, i model, and t period which runs from 1 to k. In that test, the term "quality" refers to size, length, width, engine weight, height, number of doors, power steering and brakes, The and other similar brand characteristics. di index represents horsepower performance vided by curb weight; the comfort index, head and leg room times width. Price refers to list or suggested factory-delivered cludes standard equipment,
retail price. It in federal excise tax,
at theU. S. Department of HUD, San Francisco Regional Office, and Professorial Lecturer of at Golden Gate University, and Adjunct Professor of Economics at JFK University.
60
THE AMERICANECONOMIST
This content downloaded from 169.229.32.36 on Thu, 2 Oct 2014 14:16:53 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
and dealer fee, and excludes taxes and transportation costs.
state and
local
and Hogarty's (1975) best specifica Boyle's tion was the log of price on the log of comfort and a dummy variable for and performance, The power amenities. log variables are weighted car the share of S. model year output. In U. by cases where import brands are used, the close comparable share data is imported new-car sales in the U.
S.
The null hypothesis(Ho) is thatestimatedlist
are nondifferent price-attribute relationships and Ford General Motors, among Corporation, American We excluded Chrysler Corporation. Motors Corporation for lack of adequate data. If the sample data by firms for each year cannot falsify the hypothesis, then we inferred that the in the price firms' pricing behavior expressed rather than attribute relationship was collusive competitive.
The test statistic is F=[[(A-B)/(T-1) where A = resid (K+1)]/[B/(N-T(K+1)]],
ual sum of squares from the combined sample, B = the residual sum of squares for each firm's = number of sample summed over firms, T = K number of independent subsamples, and N = size. Although variables, sample
Boyle and Hogarty [1975] suggested a five percent significant level, we considered a wider band as well. We have drawn the sample to allow compar ison with Boyle's and Hogarty's results. Before from Corporation dropping American Motors the study, we verified that its data yielded singular matrix solutions inmost years. Some of the limitations on the sample size are listed below. are ?Models characteristic data lacking omitted. ?Convertibles
and
station wagons
are not
used.
?If engine
the difference specification,
in a model is due only to then all themodels are not
used.
is available either as (1) a (2) a 4-door sedan, or (3) a hard-top, only the 2-door sedan is used. Another consequence of these limitations is that they did not yield enough observations on foreign firm to test the hypothesis that U. S. firms have colluded with foreign firms for those to Sande years we conducted the test. According ?If 2-door
the model sedan,
Milton (1986), for a t-value of 2, an R2 of 0.9, three independent variables (k), and a minimum addition to r2 of .01 when a new variable is = k + i.e., n added, we need 44 observations,
1+
[t^l-R^/r2]
= 3 +
1+
(4*.1)/.01
=
This represents nearly half the size of all import brands in 1986. For pragmatic reasons therefore, we have created one hypothetical import firm, comprising of all import models. The data come primarily from the "Automo tive News Market Data Book Issue" for each some we In have used "Ward's instances, year. Automotive Year Book", for model especially we offered for share data. The explanations are drawn firms' behavior from generally available sources such as the Business Periodical Index, the New York Times Index, Advertising Age, and Auto Basics. 44.
Results
and Discussions
1 and 2 show, As Tables a explained large percentage
the variables have of variation in list
price.Except for 1984, 1985 and 1987, thelevel
the coefficients appears fairly stable. The dummy variable was highly significant in all years except in 1986, and 1987. The intercept of
TABLE 1
Regression Equations forList Price on Index of Comfort, Performance, and a Dummy Variable for Power Steering and Brakes, 1972-1987 Critical Point at Year
Test Statistics
Distribution
10 5 percent
1972 2.06912 2.046 F(8,84) 1973 2.01411 2.024 F(8,107) 1974 2.49475 2.030 F(8,100) 1975 2.01783 2.024 F(8,108) 1976 2.35469 2.024 F(8,108) 1977 2.42542 2.036 F(8,94) 1978 5.08283 2.038 F(8,92)* 1979 2.27523 2.042 F(8,88) 1980 2.86131 2.048 F(8,82)* 1981 3.86580 2.045 F(8,85)* 1982 0.95454 2.060 F(8,75) 1983 6.17138 2.040 F(8,90)* 1984 2.47562 2.037 F(8,93) 1985 1.91026 2.047 F(8,83) 1986 4.88289 2.047 F(8,83)* 1987 1.59526 2.047 F(8,83) * Indicates reject homogeneity hypothesis.
Vol. 35, No. 2 (Fall 1991) 61
This content downloaded from 169.229.32.36 on Thu, 2 Oct 2014 14:16:53 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
percent 2.736 2.679 2.690 2.677 2.677 2.705 2.71 2.72 2.735 2.728 2.755 2.715 2.707 2.733 2.733 2.733
TABLE 2
Regression Equations Year
forList Price on Index of Comfort, Performance, and a Dummy Variable Steering and Brakes, 1972-1987 Comfort
Intercept
1.1301972
0.730 0.243
0.455
095
(2.548)* 0.260 0.325
(10.963)*
(2.327)*
(9.018)*
(3.109)*
(9.255)*
(3.786)* 3.868 1975
(3.715)* 0.398
(6.629)*
(5.206)* 4.044 1976
(4.056)* 0.406
(3.977)* 0.531 0.241 (5.245)* 0.594 0.182 (4.710)* 0.298 (4.607)* 0.257 (1.547) 0.338 0.428 (1.996)* 0.649 0.306
3.387 1974
(4.441)* 3.961 1977 (4.312)* 1.095 1978 2.197 1979
0.435
(4.170)* 0.250
(4.839)* 3.388 1981
(1.649) 0.550
(2.634)* 3.300 1982
(3.108)* 0.495
(3.297)* 0.611 1983
(3.184)* 0.930 (6.146)* (0.554) 1.081 (10.415)* 1.108
(0.537) -0.564 1985 (0.582)
5.565 1986
(10.608)* 0.363 1987 Significant at 0.05;
** =
the weakest.
0.493 0.258
(3.435)* 0.411 0.582 (3.411)* 0.827 0.204 (1.137) (6.442)* 0.677
(1.815)** 5.232 1980
-0.4111984
term was
R2
(1.576) (7.563)* 0.700
1.388 1973
*
Performance Dummy
(7.467)* (5.128)* (7.316)*
(3.634)* 1.017
(10.007)* (1.488) -0.0640.001
0.94 0.96 0.97
0.94 (6.718)* (5.431)* (5.860)* (3.459)*
(3.857)*
0.96 0.95 0.98 0.97 0.96
(3.765)*
0.699 0.263
0.94
0.93
(8.335)*
(8.431)*
0.96
0.95
(6.319)*
(4.660)* 0.432 0.291 (2.630)* 0.447 0.335 (3.041)* 0.041 0.245 (0.274) -0.0720.379 (0.679) -0.079 0.431 (0.598)
0.256
for Power
0.95 0.93
_(0.214)_(4.337)*_(0.273)_(1.285)_ Significant at 0.1.
It performed
poorly
in
1972, 1978, 1979, 1983, 1985, and 1987. Apparently,itcorrelatedhighlywith thedummy fitting a constant with a near perfect power dummy variable has not been a problem for this model up to 1987. No singular matrix solution resulted, and an attempt to force variable. However,
themodel through the origin resulted in negative index was weak in 1978, R2. The performance 1983, 1984, and 1985, and the comfort index was weak only in 1980. The negative coefficients for the performance
index in 1984, 1985 and 1987 do not falsifythe
hypothesis. The year 1984 marked a comeback firms. Firms of performance for domestic
the stepped up nonprice competition against increased share of imports. In that year, General Motors positioned the firstAmerican mid-engine Pontiac Fiero. sports car, and the wedge-shape as a new perfor Chrysler pitted the Daytona new mance turbo car, and Ford mobilized charged and diesel engines for its Mustang, firm and Lynx. Each Cougar, Capri, Topaz an excess of 200 horsepower. offered engine in At the same time, American cars were becoming lighter with more high-stress and high-strength plastic styling. In 1987, 80 percent of the cars were fitted with four- and six-cylinder. The full effect of performance in those years were only partly captured
in the performance
index. The
62 THE AMERICANECONOMIST
This content downloaded from 169.229.32.36 on Thu, 2 Oct 2014 14:16:53 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
residual that picked up the other part appeared to have dominated the horsepower to weight ratio we have used. The net result was negative coefficients in those years. As no superfluous we in the specification, variables appeared
followed the advise of Rao andMiller (1971,
in keeping the equations. the test statistics with the critical Comparing points of the F-distribution, the results of Table 2 indicate that we should have no doubt in pp. 38-46)
accepting thehypothesis in 1973, 1975, 1982, 1987. At the ten percent significance 1985, we it in eleven of the should accept level, sixteen years. However, we should reject it in
1978, 1980, 1981, 1983, 1986. Why did the hypothesis fail in those five
years? In 1978, the "interim pricing" policies described above were practiced. In 1980, firms to increased prices every quarter in response a manufacturer will inflation rates. "Sometimes toss in an extra hike, as Chrysler did inMarch on Omni and Horizon." (Automotive News,
1980, p. 62) In 1981, Ford Motor Company and Chrysler Corporation hesitated to follow leader's "GM hiked prices a substantial price policy.
$351 effective April 13,bringingits 1981-model
year average to $914 and pushing the average GM car above ten price of the average-equipped on that It become thousand dollars. $10,200 date.
Then came a couple of surprises. Ford, which almost always follows GM in such matters, said itwould not hike prices before the end of April. And Chrysler said it would make no increase 'until absolutely necessary'." (Automotive News.,
1981, p. 50)
In 1983, the U. S. auto makers were looking for newer direction in pricing that year's It was the third year in which models. the was in recession. General Motors' industry
average price increase was somewhat flat, 1.9 percent. Still, the other firms were reluctant to follow. Ford Motor average price Company increase was a modest 0.4 percent. Chrysler went the other way, cutting the base sticker price on its convertibles and other models. In 1986, General Motors reduced its incentive programs as the industry had itsmost profitable second year in 1985. Its average price increase was 2.9 percent or about $350 per unit. Chrysler Corporation again refused to follow, reducing to prices on its Omni and Plymouth Horizon
current base below of $710 prices subcompacts. Table 3 presents additional tests for the years the hypothesis has failed. We attempted to find different grouping of firms that set prices results show that General uniformly. The Motors and Ford Motor Company have colluded in 1986. The leadership role had changed in that year with Ford Motor Company topping General in earning, reversing a historic trend Motors since 1924. Chrysler Corporation behavior in to corroborate Schwartz going alone appears man's words that "Small firm . . .will be more inclined to utilize price cuts in an effort to increase sales" [1970, p. 107]. The subgrouping of firms also indicate that Chrysler Corporation had abandoned the price-cartel in 1986. The voluntary import quotas of the 1980's has raised the issue as to whether the domestic firms accommodated, extinguished or neutralized for about
and Lindsey eign firms' price policy. Dolan an have that international (1988, p. 960), argued automobile cartel was formed between Japan to the price benefits and the U. S. consequent firms have enjoyed. We have tested the price hypothesis with domestic vs. imported models to identify any international price-cartel. Data limited the test to the broad availability U. S. of and U. S. firms vs. all hypothesis
Importsfor 1983, and 1986. Table 4 displays
the results. The results indicate a high probability that the domestic and foreign firms do not price the characteristic of their product similarly for the two years in which the price-collusion hypothe sis failed for the domestic the industry. Given experimental nature of the domestic firms price policies, and the propensity of Chrysler Corpo ration, the smallest firm in the cartel, to cheat,
thedomestic firmsbehavior in 1983 and 1986
as neither openly extinguishing nor appeared but mostly neutral. Only the accommodating, smallest firm exhibited extinguishing tenden cies. General Motors and Ford Motor Company preferred the oligopoly with differentiated prod such as R&D, uct, choosing nonprice weapons advertising, styling, dealership arrangements, over price competition to rival foreign competi tion.
Our findings allow the inference that domestic firms in the automobile industry followed a uniform price policy when foreign competition
Vol. 35, No. 2 (Fall 1991) 63
This content downloaded from 169.229.32.36 on Thu, 2 Oct 2014 14:16:53 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
TABLE 3
Regression Equations
forList Price on Index of Comfort, Performance, and a Dummy Variable Steering and Brakes, Several Years
for Power
Results for Ford and General Motors only Year
Comfort
Intercept
1978
0.736 0.868 (0.707) 1980 4.705
1983 1986
Performance Dummy
(3.309)* 1981 3.229 (1.702)**
(2.234)**
(0.999) (6.527)* 0.335 (2.925)* (6.176)* 0.412 0.299 (1.575) (3.969)*
(2.52)*
(9.958)*
0.866 0.893 (4.379)* 5.748 0.181
(0.580)
0.073 0.296 (0.359) (3.687)* 0.708 0.487
j
1978
1986
096
(6.255)* 0.309 0.563 (1.585) 0.572
(10.155)
Year
R2
0.143 0.298
Distribution
5 percent10
F(4,80)
2.330 3.250
1.64459*
F(4,57)
0.97 0.93
tCritical Points at
6.79265
F(4,66) F(4,66) F(4,70)
0.99
(1.996)
Statistics 1980 4.00582 5.48495 1981 7.79162 1983
0.91
percent
2.508 3.616 2.508 3.616 2.517 4.100
2.462 3.677
Results for Ford and Chrysler only Year
Comfort
Intercept
1978
1983
1986
-0.614 1.103 (-0.410) -0.106 1980
(5.447)* 1.004
(-0.044) 1981 -2.929
(3.005)* 1.425
(-1.682)
(5.850) -2.464 1.389
(-1.773)
(7.193)*
0.247 5.517
(9.746)*
Year
1978 1983
(3.813)*
Statistics
Distribution
6.79265
F(4,80)
4.00582 1980 5.48495 1981
F(4,66) F(4,66)
8.31193
F(4,44)
Performance Dummy
R2
0.079 0.263
0.95
(0.382) -0.014 0.241
(3.744)*
(-0.045) (2.841)* -0.358 0.222 (-1.654) (3.535)* -0.339 0.133 (-1.826) (1.548)
0.720 0.338
(10.864)*
0.93 0.98 0.98
0.97
(1.045)
at TCritical Points 5 percent 10percent
2.330 3.250
2.508 3.616 3.616 2.508
2.594 3.794
1986_6.98958_F(4,37)_2.634_3.887_ Source: Estimate by author. was
weak. foreign Strong caused Chrysler Corporation
has competition to break away
from traditionalpricing policies. While import competition was not significantly disruptive to in eleven of the sixteen domestic price policies
years between
1972 to 1987,
its force was most
visible in 1978, 1980, 1981, 1983, and 1986.
The domestic industry showed its thick skin in those disruptive years when import quotas were to step up in place. Firms had the chance
64
THE AMERICAN ECONOMIST
This content downloaded from 169.229.32.36 on Thu, 2 Oct 2014 14:16:53 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
TABLE 4
Regression Equations
forList Price on Index of Comfort, Performance, and a Dummy Variable Steering and Brakes, 1983, 1986 and ImportModels
Results forDomestic
(3.435)*
0.442 4.252 (2.594)* 0.123 6.528
(9.987)*
(1.442)
1983 1986
Performance Dummy R2
Comfort
Year Intercept
for Power
0.95
0.361 0.542 (3.458)* (3.266) 0.869 0.495
0.93
(2.173)*
(10.384)
Critical Points at t 5 percent10 percent j
Distribution
Statistics Year 8.69026 1983+ 4.36084 1983# 7.91789 1986+ +
3.32 2.37 1.75 2.18 2.37 3.32
F(4,152) F(12,144) F(4,171)
1986#_4.29709_F(12,163)_L75_ Firms vs. Imports: # indicates Domestic
indicates U.S.
nonprice competition, maintaining their differen status quo, while tiated oligopoly avoiding with foreign firms in setting price cooperating policies.
2.18_ vs. Imports.
The Automobile Industry [New Epstein, Ralph C, York: A. W. Shaw Company, 1928]. Ferber,
R.,
Bibliography Boyle, Stanley E., and Hogarty, Thomas F., Pricing Behavior in the American Automobile Industry, 1957-71, The Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. XXIV (December, 1975). Bradley, Albert, in the Eighty-fourth Cong., First Sess., Senate Subcommittee on Antitrust and Senate Committee on the Judiciary, Monopoly, 1955, Pt. 7. P. Hearings on General Motors, 3593. Brown, Donaldson, Pricing Policy in Relation to Control,
Management
and
Administra
tion, (February, 1924). Caves, duct,
Richard,
American
Performance
[N.
Structure, Industry: J.: Prentice-Hall,
Con Inc.,
(Second Edition), 1964]. Chamberlin, Edward H., The Theory ofMonopolistic Competition [Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1965]. Dhrymes, Phoebus J., Price and Quality Changes in Consumer Capital Goods: An Empirical Study, in Griliches, Z. (ed.), Price Indexes and Quality Change [Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1971]. Dolan, Edwin G. and Lindsey, David E., Econom ics, 5th Edition [N.Y.: The Dryden Press, 1988]. Edwards, Charles E., The Dynamics of the United States Automobile Industry [Columbia: University of South Carolina Press, 1965].
Verdoorn,
P.
and Business
J., Research
Methods
Non-Price
Competi
[N.Y.: The Macmillan
1962]
Company, Havrilesky,
Financial
and
inEconomics T.,
and
Barth,
R.,
tion in the Cigarette Industry, The Antitrust Bulletin, XIV (Fall, 1969), pp. 607-628. Hogarty, Thomas, Price-Quality Relations for Auto mobiles: A New Approach, Applied Economics, Vol. 7, 1975, pp. 41-51. Kennedy, E. D., The Automobile Industry, The Coming of Age of Capitalism's Favorite Child [New York: Reynal and Hitchcock, 1941]. Kwoka, Jr., John E., Market Power and Market Change in the U. S. Automobile Industry, The Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. XXXII
(June, 1984). Lanzillotti, Robert F., The Automobile Industry in Adams, Walter, (ed.) The Structure of American Industry [New York: The Macmillan Company, (Third Edition), 1961]. Maxcy, G., and Silberston, A., The Motor Industry [London: Allen and Unwin, 1959] Milton, Sande, A Sample Size Formula for Multiple Regression Studies, Public Opinion Quarterly, Vol. 50, Spring 1986. Moore, Donald A., The Automobile Industry In Adams, Walter, (ed.), The Structure of American Industry [New York: The Macmillan Company, (Revised Edition), 1954]. Polk, R. L., inAutomotive News, 1988, p. 32. Industrial Market Structure and Scherer, F. M., Economic Performance [Chicago: Rand McNally College Publishing Company, 1970 (revised 1980)].
Vol. 35, No. 2 (Fall 1991) 65
This content downloaded from 169.229.32.36 on Thu, 2 Oct 2014 14:16:53 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Roa, Potluri and Miller, Roger L., Applied Econo metrics [Belmont: Wadsworth Publishing Com
pany, Inc., 1971] Schwartzman, David, Oligopoly in theFarm Machin ery Industry [Canada: Royal Commission on Farm Machinery, Study No. 12, 1970] Sherman, Roger, Oligopoly: An Empirical Approach [Mass.: Lexington Books, 1972]
Telser, Lester G., Competition, Collusion, and Game Theory [Chicago: Aldine and Atherton, 1972]. White, Lawrence J., The Automobile Industry Since 1945 [Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1971]. White, Lawrence J., The Automobile Industry in Adams, Walter (ed.), The Structure of American Industry [New York: Macmillan Publishing Co., Inc., 1977].
66
THE AMERICANECONOMIST
This content downloaded from 169.229.32.36 on Thu, 2 Oct 2014 14:16:53 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions