Document not found! Please try again

A Taxonomy of Industries Based on Knowledge Flow Structure

0 downloads 0 Views 145KB Size Report
YONG-TAE PARK & MOON-SOO KIM. ABSTRACT. With the advent of the knowledge-based economy, the inter-industrial ow of technological knowledge is ...
Technology Analysis & Strategic Management, Vol. 11, No. 4, 1999

A Taxonomy of Industries Based on Knowledge Flow Structure

YONG-TAE PARK & MOON-SOO KIM

A BSTRACT With the advent of the knowledge-based economy, the inter-industrial ow of technological knowledge is reckoned as the principal determinant of national competitiveness. The mode of knowledge ows, however, is intractably complex. Taking it as a network, this paper aims at providing an inductive taxonomy of industries based on the knowledge ow structure and thus identifying the user–supplier relationship among industries in terms of knowledge diffusion. Some proxy indexes are developed Žrst to measure the knowledge ows, then the interactive mechanism among industries is investigated by the network analysis and eventually a taxonomy of industries is presented according to the characteristics of respective industries. The taxonomic approach highlights the importance of inter-industrial knowledge management system that facilitates knowledge ows across industries based on the idiosyncratic features of respective industries. Introduction With the advent of the knowledge-based economy, the notion of national systems of innovation becomes highlighted in the arena of policy practice and innovation research.1 The notion premises that technological knowledge be created, accumulated and disseminated through the interactive learning among principal actors in national system. In particular, the  ow of technological knowledge across industries is reckoned as the principal determinant of national competitiveness. The mode of knowledge  ows across industries, however, is intractably complex. It collectively constitutes a network in which various nodes release, absorb or intermediate technological knowledge. In dealing with diverse objects with multiple dimensionality, taxonomic approaches are often adopted to construct a building block for ensuing analyses. Among others, the inter-industrial knowledge linkage accounts for an important dimension of classiŽ cation. Let alone the formal standard industry classiŽ cation(SIC), probably the most well-known classiŽ cation scheme is due to Pavitt.2 He proposes a taxonomy in which Ž rms are clustered in terms of sources of technology, types of user, means of appropriation and Ž rm size to form such distinct categories as supplier-dominated, scale-intensive, specialized-suppliers and science-based industries. Malerba3 dichotomizes Ž rms into basic component and system industry and system application industry according to competitive edges, organizational strategy and government policy. Yong-Tae Park is an Assistant Professor at the Department of Industrial Engineering, School of Engineering, Seoul National University, San 56–1, Shillim-Dong, Kwanak-Gu, Seoul 151–742, Korea; Tel: 82–2–880–8358; Fax: 82–2–889–8560; E-mail:pk [email protected] l . Moon-Soo Kim is a senior researcher at the Electronic and Telecommunications Research Institute (ETRI), Taejon, Korea. The authors thank the editor and anonymous referees for valuable comments that helped to improve this article. ISSN 1465-399 0 online/ISSN 0953-7325 /99/040541-09

Ó

1999 Taylor & Francis Ltd.

542

Y.-T. Park & M.-S. Kim

In fact, these schemes represent the empiricism of such conceptual notions as paradigm,4 trajectory5 or guidepost6 that contrast the sector-speciŽ c pattern of innovation across industries. The validity and utility of these schemes, albeit meaningful, is limited in that they may highlight the idiosyncratic features of respective industries but may not identify the interactive relationship among industries. In the knowledgebased economy, it is more important to understand the inter-industry linkage structure among industries, rather than to understand the individual characteristics of respective industries. Along this line, this paper aims at providing an inductive taxonomy of industries based on the knowledge  ow structure and thus identifying the user–supplier relationship among industries in terms of knowledge diffusion. Intuitively, in the course of economic development and industrial sophistication, some industries may generate (out ow) knowledge whereas others may use (in ow) or intermediate (in-between) knowledge. We will Ž rst develop some proxy indexes that can measure the knowledge  ows, then investigate the interactive mechanism among industries by the network analysis and eventually present a taxonomy of industries according to the characteristics of respective industries. Types of Knowledge Flow and Network Analysis Measuring Knowledge

We measure the knowledge, as a proxy, by the number of researchers. That is, it is assumed that the more researchers in an industry, the larger technological knowledge in it. This knowledge measure is represented as knowledge matrix H , whose diagonal hii denotes total amount of knowledge in ith industry and off-diagonal hij is zero. Two Major Types of Knowledge Flow

By and large, the  ow of knowledge takes place through two major channels, disembodied and embodied one. The former is the process whereby technological knowledge spreads through human mobility and research spillovers across industries. Due to intrinsic difŽ culty of measurement, we use the technological similarity matrix S, as a proxy, to measure the inter-industrial disembodied knowledge  ow. The matrix is deŽ ned as follows whose element sij is measured in a similar way to Jaffe7 S5

[sij] where, sij 5 Ï

Fi FTj (FiFTi )(FjF Tj )

Row vector Fi indicates the number of researchers with their academic Ž elds (30 majors with subscript k) and 3-degree types (PhD, master, bachelor with subscript l ) in i th industry: Fi 5

[ fikl ]

Instead of arbitrarily assigning different weights, all degree types are weighted equally. Combining H and S , the disembodied knowledge  ow matrix K D is constructed: KD 5

H 3

S5

[k dij]

The embodied channel, on the other hand, is the process whereby knowledge is disseminated through the purchase of machinery, equipment and components incorporating new technology. In this process, some industries act as suppliers or sellers of

Taxonomy of Industries

543

intermediate and capital goods whereas other industries act as users or buyers, both constituting a technology diffusion network. The embodied knowledge  ows across industries are measured, again as a proxy, based on the coefŽ cients of the Leontief inverse.8 The coefŽ cient embraces both direct  ow (from industry i to industry j ) and indirect  ow (from industry i to industry j via industry k). Thus, a transformation matrix T is constructed where X means diagonal matrix of industrial output, [I 2 A d] 2 1 denotes domestic Leontief inverse and D indicates diagonal matrix of Ž nal demand: T5

[I 2

X2

A d] 2

1

1

D

Combining H and T , the embodied knowledge  ow matrix K E is obtained: KE 5

H 3

T5

[k eij]

The proxy measures proposed here are subject to some limitations since the inter-industrial distribution of technical personnel and the values in the input–output table may encompass other factors than technological knowledge embodiment. Granting that, they are considered to be comprehensive and representative enough to re ect the knowledge  ows across industries and similar measures were often employed by previous research.9 Network Analysis

In general, the interactive relationship among actors can be portrayed as a network.10 Network analysis, a quantitative technique derived from graph theory, facilitates the analysis of interactions (edges) between entities (nodes). The above knowledge matrix K can be easily converted into the network G v (N , L, V) where N , L, V indicate industries, inter-industrial  ow relations and inter-industrial  ow amount, respectively. However, the graph becomes intractably complex as the number of nodes increases. Hence, excluding negligible relations from further analysis, G V is transformed into a dichotomized graph G D by using cut-off values: Gv Þ

G D(N , L D),

where, L D 5 and,

{l dij}

l dij 5

1 for vij .

cutoff

l 5

0 for vij #

cutoff, "

d ij

i, j 5

1,2, … g

Then, the overall connectivity of network is measured based on the density of network: D5

ld g( g 2

1)

, where l d 5

O O i

l dij j

Here, g means the total number of nodes (industries), denominator indicates the maximum number of connections between nodes and numerator denotes the actual number of connections. Therefore the inter-industrial linkage of network increases as density increases. Empirical Analysis Empirical Data

The set of empirical data covers manufacturing sector of Korea during 1980s. The reference period is of particular importance in the chronology of Korea in that industrial base reached the critical mass to embark on indigenous private R&D. Hence, it is

544

Y.-T. Park & M.-S. Kim Table 1. The selected list of 34 manufacturing industries Number 1 2 3 4 5

Industry

Number

Industry

18 19 20 21 22

Ferrous Metals Nonferrous Metals Fabricated Metal Products Boilers and Turbines Special Industrial Machinery

6 7

Food and Beverages Textile Wood and Furniture Paper and Printing Industrial Organic and Inorganic Chemicals Dyes and Paint Agricultural Chemicals

23 24

8 9

Pharmaceuticals Toiletry and Cleansers

25 26

10

Other Chemical Products (explosives, adhesives)

27

11

Petroleum Extraction and ReŽ ning Mining

28

Rubber Products Plastic Products Porcelain and Earthenware Glass Products

30 31 32

Cement, Stone and Clay Products

34

Fabrication Machinery Computer and OfŽ ce Equipment Other Machinery Industrial Electrical Equipment Video, Audio and Telecommunication Equipment Household Electrical Equipment Semi-Conductor and Electronic Components Other Electrical Equipment Shipbuilding Motor Vehicles and Equipment Other Transportation Equipment Precision Equipment (measuring and medical instruments, photo equipment, and timepieces)

12 13 14 15 16 17

29

33

assessed that both disembodied and embodied  ow channels were constructed and operated during 1980s to form a genuine inter-industrial knowledge network. For the disembodied knowledge  ow matrices, the annuals, from 1982 to 1991, of the Korea Industrial Technology Association (KITA) are used.11 The database includes R&D workforce of private Ž rms with their academic Ž elds and degree types. For the embodied knowledge  ow matrices, the input–output tables of the Korea Bank during the same period are adopted.12 In total, 34 manufacturing industries are included, as displayed in Table 1. Taxonomy of Industries General Trend

The overall connectivity among industries can be measured by the degree of density. As exhibited in Figure 1, density of disembodied network has steadily increased irrespective of cutoff values throughout 1980s. The case of embodied knowledge network shows similar pattern of evolution. As portrayed in Figure 2, there appeared a sharp increase from 1983 to 1987, followed by gradual growth afterwards. This fact conŽ rms the hypothetical rule of evolution that the connectivity among industries be strengthened over time to form a more structured network, as industries require both internal knowledge and external knowledge during the course of develop-

Taxonomy of Industries

545

Figure 1. Density of disembodied knowledge  ow. ment. The result also provides the validity and feasibility of classiŽ cation since taxonomic clusters become discernible as the density increases. Inow–Outow Position Map

As the overall connectivity of network is enhanced, inter-industrial linkages become more visible. The visibility, however, depends on the cut-off value adopted. Thus, instead of selecting a particular cut-off value, we simply measure the knowledge  ow amounts of each industry for both disembodied and embodied cases. Then, taking the industry averages as center lines, each industry can be located in a two-dimensional map either

Figure 2. Density of embodied knowledge  ow.

546

Y.-T. Park & M.-S. Kim

Figure 3. Knowledge in ow position map. as high (above average) or low (below average). To illustrate, if a particular industry absorbs more disembodied knowledge than the overall average, it is classiŽ ed as ‘high’ in terms of disembodied-in ow dimension. By doing so, the following in ow–out ow position maps, Figure 3 and 4, can be created. Note that some outlying industries are not plotted in the maps. Taxonomy of Industries

In order to apply a statistical clustering algorithm, the dissimilarities of industries in the position matrix are required to be quantiŽ ed. However, it is very difŽ cult to identify the exact address of respective industries by numerical description. Thus, taxonomic clusters are contrasted in a qualitative manner. For each cluster, afŽ liated industries are assessed in a qualitative scale, either high or low depending on the relative level of knowledge in ow or out ow amounts. By doing so, we end up with the following ten clusters: The industries in this sector are characterized by high degree of out ow in terms of both disembodied and embodied knowledge and, 1. Both outow and disembodied-inow sector.

Taxonomy of Industries

547

Figure 4. Knowledge out ow position map.

simultaneously, high degree of disembodied knowledge in ow. The afŽ liated industries include chemicals (5), industrial electrical equipment (26) and precision equipment (34).

The industries in this sector are characterized by high degree of in ow with respect to both disembodied and embodied knowledge and, simultaneously, high degree of disembodied knowledge out ow. The afŽ liated industries include household electrical equipment (28), semi-conductor and electronic components (29) and motor vehicles and equipment (32). 2. Both inow and disembodied-outow sector.

The industries in this sector are characterized by high degree of in ow in terms of both disembodied and embodied knowledge but low degree of knowledge out ow. Hence, this sector mainly absorbs knowledge from external industries without providing internal knowledge to other sectors. Such industries as fabricated metal products (20) and other machinery (25) belong to this sector. 3. Both inow and no-outow sector.

548

Y.-T. Park & M.-S. Kim

The industries in this sector are characterized by high degree of disembodied knowledge  ow, both in ow and out ow, but low degree of embodied knowledge  ow. The afŽ liated industries include special industrial machinery (22) and telecommunications equipment (27). 4. Disembodied-ow sector.

The industries in this sector are characterized by high degree of out ow in terms of disembodied knowledge and high degree of in ow with respect to embodied knowledge. The textile industry (2) belongs to this category. 5. Disembodied-outow and embodied-inow sector.

The industries in this sector are characterized by high degree of out ow in terms of embodied knowledge. Other knowledge  ows, however, are not active. The afŽ liated industries include dyes and paint (6), explosives and adhesives (10), rubber products (13) and glass products (16). 6. Embodied-outow sector.

The industries in this sector are characterized by high degree of disembodied knowledge out ow. However, other knowledge  ows are not notable. The afŽ liated industries include pharmaceuticals (8), plastic products (14), nonferrous metals (19), fabrication machine (23), computers and ofŽ ce equipment (24), other electrical equipment (30) and other transportation equipment (33). 7. Disembodied-outow sector.

The industries in this sector are characterized by high degree of disembodied knowledge in ow. The afŽ liated industries include boilers and turbines (21) and shipbuilding (31). 8. Disembodied-inow sector.

The industries in this sector are characterized by high degree of embodied knowledge in ow. The food and beverage industry (1) corresponds to this category. 9. Embodied-inow sector.

The industries in this sector are disconnected or very loosely connected with other industries in terms of knowledge  ow. Such industries as wood and furniture (3), paper and printing (4), agricultural chemicals (7), toiletry and cleansers (9), petroleum extraction and reŽ ning (11), mining (12), porcelain and earthenware (15), cement and stone and clay products (17) and ferrous metal (18) are included in this category. 10. Knowledge-isolated sector.

Conclusion The emerging economic and social paradigm rests on the two underlying notions of knowledge and network. Inter-industrial linkages are expanded and intensiŽ ed due to technological knowledge  ows, both disembodied and embodied, and the interconnected structure as a whole forms a complex network. The analysis of this network is a necessary but difŽ cult task. In the spirit of exploration, we adopt the network theory and develop a new taxonomic framework of industries based on the role of respective industries in terms of knowledge  ows. The taxonomy is distinct from conventional ones in that it highlights the idiosyncratic features of respective industries not only from the sectorspeciŽ c view but also from network-related view. This dual perspective is the main advantage of the new taxonomy over the existing classiŽ cations. Various industries are located on the in ow–out ow and disembodied–embodied position maps and ten

Taxonomy of Industries

549

discernable clusters are identiŽ ed according to the relative standings on the maps. Each cluster, then, represents distinctive position in the inter-industrial knowledge network. The taxonomy renders some important policy implications. First, it is required to monitor the changing trend of knowledge  ows across industries and construct the optimal structure of national knowledge systems accordingly. The structural changes then should be dynamically addressed in industrial policy. Educational institutes and labor market also should be maneuverable enough to respond to the changing trend. Second, industry-speciŽ c policy measures should be applied depending on the nature of respective industries. Some industries may need to reinforce productive capacity whereas others need to enhance absorptive capability. Intermediary sectors need to be armed with facilitating and catalyzing vehicles. This paper is rather seminal and subject to some limitations. First, the taxonomy proposed here per se is period-speciŽ c. It merely re ects an evolutionary snapshot of the reference period, and thus must be interpreted so. The clusters may be reshuf ed if different periods are adopted. Second, in the similar vein, the taxonomy is countryspeciŽ c. It depends on the development stage and industrial structure of a particular country. Third, the proxy measures employed may re ect other factors than technological knowledge  ow. These limitations, however, by no means hamper the validity and utility of the research since the purpose of this paper is not to provide a generic taxonomic scheme but to suggest an analytical framework that is universally applicable regardless of speciŽ c proŽ les. Notes and References 1.

2. 3. 4.

5. 6. 7. 8. 9.

10.

11. 12.

B-A. Lundvall, National Systems of Innovation—Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning (London, Pinter, 1992); R. Nelson (Ed.), National Innovation System (Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1993). K. Pavitt, ‘Sectoral Patterns of Technical Change: Towards a Taxonomy and a Theory’, Research Policy , 13 , 1984, pp. 343–373. F. Malerba, ‘The Organization of the Innovative Process’, in: N. Rosenberg, R. Landau & D. Mowery (Eds), Technology and the Wealth of Nations (Stanford University Press, 1992). T. Kuhn, The Structure of ScientiŽ c Revolutions (Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1970); G. Dosi, ‘Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change’, Research Policy, 2 (3), 1982, pp. 147–162; C. Freeman & C. Perez, ‘Structural Crises of Adjustment: Business Cycles and Investment Behavior’, in: G. Dosi (Ed), Technical Change and Economic Theory (London, Printer, 1988). Dosi, ibid. D. Sahal, ‘Technological Guideposts and Innovation Avenues’, Research Policy, 14 , 1985, pp. 61–82. A Jaffe, ‘Technological Opportunity and Spillovers of R&D: Evidence from Firms’ Patents, PorŽ ts, and Market Value’, American Economic Review , 76 (55), 1986, pp. 984–1001. P. Mohnen, ‘R&D Externality and Productivity Growth’, STI Review , 7, 1996, pp. 39–66. Ibid. ; R. Leoncini, M. Maggioni & S. Montressor, ‘Intersectorial Innovation Flows and National Technological System Network Analysis for Comparing Italy and Germany’, Research Policy, 25 , 1996 pp. 415–430; A. Goto & K. Suzuki, ‘R&D Capital, Rate of Return on R&D Investment and Spillover of R&D in Japanese Manufacturing Industries’, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 71 (4), 1989, pp. 555–564. L. Gelsing, ‘Innovation and the Development of Industrial Networks’, in: B-A. Lundvall (Ed.), National Systems of Innovation-Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning (London, Pinter, 1992). Korea Industrial Technology Association, Survey on Industrial Technological Development of Korea (Annuals from 1982 to 1991). Korea Bank, (1983, 1987, 1990).

Suggest Documents